Misplaced Pages

Gini coefficient: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editNext edit →Content deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 03:01, 4 October 2006 edit128.36.59.94 (talk) Optimal gini-coefficient← Previous edit Revision as of 22:13, 18 May 2007 edit undo190.64.76.206 (talk)No edit summaryNext edit →
(110 intermediate revisions by 66 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
] ]


The '''Gini coefficient''' is a measure of inequality of a distribution, defined as the ] of area between the ] of the distribution and the curve of the uniform distribution, to the area under the uniform distribution. It is often used to measure ] inequality. It is a ] between 0 and 1, where 0 corresponds to perfect equality (i.e. everyone has the same income) and 1 corresponds to perfect inequality (i.e. one person has all the income, while everyone else has zero income). It was developed by the ] ] ] and published in his ] paper "Variabilità e mutabilità" ("Variability and Mutability"). The Gini coefficient is equal to half of the ]. The '''Gini index''' is the Gini coefficient expressed as a ], and is equal to the Gini coefficient multiplied by 100. The '''Gini coefficient''' is a measure of inequality of a distribution of income. It is defined as a ] with values between 0 and 1: the numerator is the area between the ] of the distribution and the uniform (perfect) distribution line; the denominator is the area under the uniform distribution line. It was developed by the ] ] ] and published in his ] paper "Variabilità e mutabilità" ("Variability and Mutability"). The '''Gini index''' is the Gini coefficient expressed as a ], and is equal to the Gini coefficient multiplied by 100. (The Gini coefficient is equal to half of the ].)


While the Gini coefficient is mostly used to measure income inequality, it can also be used to measure ] ] This use requires that no one has a negative net wealth. The Gini coefficient is often used as an ]. (See that article for discussion of the social aspects of income inequality.) Here, 0 corresponds to perfect income equality (i.e. everyone has the same income) and 1 corresponds to perfect income inequality (i.e. one person has all the income, while everyone else has zero income).


Gini coefficient is today commonly used for the measurement of discriminatory power of ] systems in the ] management.{{fact}} The Gini coefficient can also be used to measure ] ]. This use requires that no one have a negative net wealth. It is also commonly used for the measurement of the discriminatory power of ] systems in ] management.


== Calculation == == Calculation ==


The Gini coefficient is defined as a ratio of the areas on the ] diagram. If the area between the line of perfect equality and Lorenz curve is A, and the area under the Lorenz curve is B, then the Gini coefficient is A/(A+B). Since A+B = 0.5, the Gini coefficient, G = 2A = 1-2B. If the Lorenz curve is represented by the function Y = L(X), the value of B can be found with ] and: The Gini coefficient is defined as a ratio of the areas on the ] diagram. If the area between the line of perfect equality and Lorenz curve is A, and the area under the Lorenz curve is B, then the Gini coefficient is A/(A+B). Since A+B = 0.5, the Gini coefficient, G = A/(.5) = 2A = 1-2B. If the Lorenz curve is represented by the function Y = L(X), the value of B can be found with ] and:
:<math>G = 1 - 2\,\int_0^1 L(X) dX </math> :<math>G = 1 - 2\,\int_0^1 L(X) dX </math>


In some cases, this equation can be applied to calculate the Gini coefficient without direct reference to the Lorenz curve. For example: In some cases, this equation can be applied to calculate the Gini coefficient without direct reference to the Lorenz curve. For example:
*For a population with values ''y''<sub>''i''</sub>, ''i'' = 1 to ''n'', that are indexed in non-decreasing order ( ''y''<sub>''i''</sub> ≤ ''y''<sub>''i''+1</sub>): *For a population uniform on the values ''y''<sub>''i''</sub>, ''i'' = 1 to ''n'', indexed in non-decreasing order ( ''y''<sub>''i''</sub> ≤ ''y''<sub>''i''+1</sub>):
:<math>G = \frac{1}{n}(n+1 - 2\,\frac{\Sigma_{i=1}^n \; (n+1-i)y_i}{\Sigma_{i=1}^n y_i})\,</math> :<math>G = \frac{1}{n}\left ( n+1 - 2 \left ( \frac{\Sigma_{i=1}^n \; (n+1-i)y_i}{\Sigma_{i=1}^n y_i} \right ) \right ) </math>


*For a ] ''f''(''y''), where ''y''<sub>''i''</sub>, ''i'' = 1 to ''n'', are the points with nonzero probabilities and which are indexed in increasing order ( ''y''<sub>''i''</sub> &lt; ''y''<sub>''i''+1</sub>): *For a ] ''f''(''y''), where ''y''<sub>''i''</sub>, ''i'' = 1 to ''n'', are the points with nonzero probabilities and which are indexed in increasing order ( ''y''<sub>''i''</sub> &lt; ''y''<sub>''i''+1</sub>):
Line 27: Line 27:


For a random sample ''S'' consisting of values ''y''<sub>''i''</sub>, ''i'' = 1 to ''n'', that are indexed in non-decreasing order ( ''y''<sub>''i''</sub> ≤ ''y''<sub>''i''+1</sub>), the statistic: For a random sample ''S'' consisting of values ''y''<sub>''i''</sub>, ''i'' = 1 to ''n'', that are indexed in non-decreasing order ( ''y''<sub>''i''</sub> ≤ ''y''<sub>''i''+1</sub>), the statistic:
:<math>G(S) = \frac{1}{n-1}(n+1 - 2\,\frac{\Sigma_{i=1}^n \; (n+1-i)y_i}{\Sigma_{i=1}^n y_i})\,</math> :<math>G(S) = \frac{1}{n-1}\left (n+1 - 2 \left ( \frac{\Sigma_{i=1}^n \; (n+1-i)y_i}{\Sigma_{i=1}^n y_i}\right ) \right )</math>


is a ] ] of the population Gini coefficient, but is not, in general, ]. Like the ], there does not exist a sample statistic that is in general an unbiased estimator of the population Gini coefficient. Confidence intervals for the population Gini coefficient can be calculated using bootstrap techniques. is a ] ] of the population Gini coefficient, but is not, in general, ]. Like the ], there does not exist a sample statistic that is in general an unbiased estimator of the population Gini coefficient. Confidence intervals for the population Gini coefficient can be calculated using bootstrap techniques.
Line 42: Line 42:
== Income Gini coefficients in the world == == Income Gini coefficients in the world ==


See complete listing in ]. A complete listing is in ]; the article ] discusses the social and policy aspects of income and asset inequality.


] [[Image:World Map Gini coefficient.png|thumb|right|500px|Gini coefficient, income distribution by country.
{| width=100%
]
|-
<br clear="both" />
| valign=top |
While most developed European nations tend to have Gini coefficients between 0.24 and 0.36, the United States Gini coefficient is above 0.4, indicating that the United States has greater inequality. Using the Gini can help quantify differences in ] and ] policies and philosophies. However it should be borne in mind that the Gini coefficient can be misleading when used to make political comparisons between large and small countries (see ] section).
{{legend|#008000|< 0.25}}
{{legend|#00c600|0.25–0.29}}
| valign=top |
{{legend|#dede00|0.30–0.34}}
{{legend|#ffce63|0.35–0.39}}
{{legend|#ffa552|0.40–0.44}}
| valign=top |
{{legend|#ff6b6b|0.45–0.49}}
{{legend|#ff0000|0.50–0.54}}
{{legend|#c60000|0.55–0.59}}
{{legend|#800000|≥ 0.60}}
| valign=top |
{{legend|#c0c0c0|N/A}}
|}
]]
While most developed European nations tend to have Gini coefficients between 0.24 and 0.36, the United States Gini coefficient is above 0.4, indicating that the United States has greater inequality. Using the Gini can help quantify differences in ] and ] policies and philosophies. However it should be borne in mind that the Gini coefficient can be misleading when used to make political comparisons between large and small countries (see ] section).


{{-}}
] ]


=== Correlation with per-capita GDP === === Correlation with per-capita GDP ===


Poor countries (those with low ]) have Gini coefficients that fall over the whole range from low (0.25) to high (0.71), while rich countries have generally low Gini coefficient (under 0.40). Poor countries (those with low ]) have Gini coefficients that fall over the whole range from low (0.25) to high (0.71), while rich countries have generally intermediate Gini coefficient (under 0.40). Generally, the lowest Gini coefficients can be found in the Scandinavian countries, as well as the recently ex-socialist countries of Eastern Europe.


=== US income gini coefficients over time === === US income gini coefficients over time ===
Line 62: Line 79:
* ]: 0.428 * ]: 0.428
* ]: 0.462 * ]: 0.462
* ]: 0.469<ref>Note that the calculation of the index for the United States was changed in 1992, resulting in an upwards shift of about 0.02 in the coefficient. Comparisons before and after that period may be misleading. (Data from the .)</ref> * ]: 0.469<ref>Note that the calculation of the index for the United States was changed in 1992, resulting in an upwards shift of about 0.02 in the coefficient. Comparisons before and after that period may be misleading. (Data from the .)</ref>


Note how this corresponds to the lowering of the highest tax bracket, for example, from 70% in the 1960s to 35% by 2000. Some argue this rise corresponds to the lowering of the highest tax bracket, for example, from 70% in the 1960s to 35% by 2000. However, many other variables that could affect the Gini coefficient have changed during this period as well. For example, much technological progress has occurred, eliminating formerly middle-class factory jobs in favor of the service sector; additionally, the economy has shifted towards professions that require higher education.


==Advantages as a measure of inequality== ==Advantages of Gini coefficient as a measure of inequality==


* The Gini coefficient's main advantage is that it is a measure of inequality by means of a ], rather than a variable unrepresentative of most of the population, such as ] or ]. * The Gini coefficient's main advantage is that it is a measure of inequality by means of a ], rather than a variable unrepresentative of most of the population, such as ] or ].
Line 82: Line 99:
** ''Transfer principle'': if income (less than the difference), is transferred from a rich person to a poor person the resulting distribution is more equal. ** ''Transfer principle'': if income (less than the difference), is transferred from a rich person to a poor person the resulting distribution is more equal.


==Disadvantages as a measure of inequality== ==Disadvantages of Gini coefficient as a measure of inequality==


* The Gini coefficient measured for a large geographically diverse country will generally result in a much higher coefficient than each of its regions has individually. For this reason the scores calculated for individual countries within the ] are difficult to compare with the score of the entire US. * The Gini coefficient measured for a large economically diverse country will generally result in a much higher coefficient than each of its regions has individually. For this reason the scores calculated for individual countries within the ] are difficult to compare with the score of the entire US.


* Comparing income distributions among countries may be difficult because benefits systems may differ. For example, some countries give benefits in the form of money while others give ], which may not be counted as income in the Lorenz curve and therefore not taken into account in the Gini coefficient. * Comparing income distributions among countries may be difficult because benefits systems may differ. For example, some countries give benefits in the form of money while others give ], which may not be counted as income in the Lorenz curve and therefore not taken into account in the Gini coefficient.
Line 96: Line 113:
* Economies with similar incomes and Gini coefficients can still have very different income distributions. This is because the Lorenz curves can have different shapes and yet still yield the same Gini coefficient. As an extreme example, an economy where half the households have no income, and the other half share income equally has a Gini coefficient of ½; but an economy with complete income equality, except for one wealthy household that has half the total income, also has a Gini coefficient of ½. * Economies with similar incomes and Gini coefficients can still have very different income distributions. This is because the Lorenz curves can have different shapes and yet still yield the same Gini coefficient. As an extreme example, an economy where half the households have no income, and the other half share income equally has a Gini coefficient of ½; but an economy with complete income equality, except for one wealthy household that has half the total income, also has a Gini coefficient of ½.


* The Gini coefficient is used to measure income more than net worth, which can be misleading. For example, is Sweden egalitarian? Sweden has a low Gini coefficient for income distribution but a high Gini coefficient for wealth (0.1% of Swedish shareholders control 25% of all shares {{Fact|date=March 2007}}).
* It is claimed that the Gini coefficient is more sensitive to the income of the middle classes than to that of the extremes.


* Too often only the Gini coefficient is quoted '''without''' describing the proportions of the quantiles used for measurement. As with other inequality coefficients, the Gini coefficient is influenced by the granularity of the measurements. For example, five 20% quantiles (low granularity) will yield a lower Gini coefficient than twenty 5% quantiles (high granularity) taken from the same distribution. * Too often only the Gini coefficient is quoted without describing the proportions of the quantiles used for measurement. As with other inequality coefficients, the Gini coefficient is influenced by the granularity of the measurements. For example, five 20% quantiles (low granularity) will yield a lower Gini coefficient than twenty 5% quantiles (high granularity) taken from the same distribution.


As one result of this criticism, additionally to or in competition with the Gini coefficient ''entropy measures'' are frequently used (e.g. the Atkinson and ] indices). These measures attempt to compare the distribution of resources by intelligent players in the market with a maximum ] ], which would occur if these players acted like non-intelligent particles in a closed system following the laws of statistical physics. As one result of this criticism, additionally to or in competition with the Gini coefficient ''entropy measures'' are frequently used (e.g. the ] and ] indices). These measures attempt to compare the distribution of resources by intelligent players in the market with a maximum ] ], which would occur if these players acted like non-intelligent particles in a closed system following the laws of statistical physics.


== Notes == == Notes ==
{{reflist}}
<references />

== Optimal gini-coefficient ==

In their Giovanni Andrea Cornia and Julius Court (2001) reach policy conclusions as to the optimal distribution of wealth. The authors recommend to pursue moderation also as to the distribution of wealth and particularly to avoid the extremes. Both very high egalitarianism and very high inequality cause slow growth. Extreme egalitarianism leads to incentive-traps, free-riding, high operation costs and corruption in the redistribution system, all reducing a country's growth potential.

However, extreme inequality also diminishes growth potential by eroding social cohesion, and increasing social unrest and social conflict, causing uncertainty of property rights. Therefore, public policy should target an 'efficient inequality range'. The authors claim that such efficiency range lies between the values of the Gini coefficients of 25 (the inequality value of a typical Northern European country) and 40 (that of countries such as China and the USA). The precise shape of the inequality-growth relationship depicted in the Chart obviously varies across countries depending upon their resource endowment, history, remaining levels of absolute poverty and available stock of social programs, as well as on the distribution of physical and human capital.

* - Lessons from 20 Years Growth Differentials in Europe (pdf 4Mb)


== References == == References ==
*Dixon, PM, Weiner J., Mitchell-Olds T, Woodley R. Bootstrapping the Gini coefficient of inequality. Ecology 1987;68:1548-1551.
*Gini C. "Variabilità e mutabilità" (1912) Reprinted in Memorie di metodologica statistica (Ed. Pizetti E, Salvemini, T). Rome: Libreria Eredi Virgilio Veschi (1955).
*{{cite journal | author=Gini, Corrado | title=Measurement of Inequality and Incomes | journal=The Economic Journal | year=1921 | volume=31 | pages=124-126}}
*{{Cite paper | author=Xu, Kuan | title=How Has the Literature on Gini's Index Evolved in the Past 80 Years? | publisher=Department of Economics, Dalhousie University | date=January, 2004 | version= | url=http://economics.dal.ca/RePEc/dal/wparch/howgini.pdf | accessdate=June 1, 2006 }}
*{{cite journal | author=Morgan, James | title=The Anatomy of Income Distribution | journal=The Review of Economics and Statistics | year=1962 | volume=44 | pages=270-283 }}
*{{cite journal | author=Gastwirth, Joseph L. | title=The Estimation of the Lorenz Curve and Gini Index | journal=The Review of Economics and Statistics | year=1972 | volume=54 | pages=306-316}}
*{{cite book | first=Sudhir | last=Anand | year=1983 | title=Inequality and Poverty in Malaysia | publisher=Oxford University Press | location=New York}} *{{cite book | first=Sudhir | last=Anand | year=1983 | title=Inequality and Poverty in Malaysia | publisher=Oxford University Press | location=New York}}
*{{cite journal | author=Brown, Malcolm | title=Using Gini-Style Indices to Evaluate the Spatial Patterns of Health Practitioners: Theoretical Considerations and an Application Based on Alberta Data | journal=Social Science Medicine | year=1994 | volume=38 | pages=1243-1256}}
*{{cite book | first=S. R. | last=Chakravarty | year=1990 | title=Ethical Social Index Numbers | publisher=Springer-Verlag | location=New York }} *{{cite book | first=S. R. | last=Chakravarty | year=1990 | title=Ethical Social Index Numbers | publisher=Springer-Verlag | location=New York }}
*{{cite journal | author=Dixon, PM, Weiner J., Mitchell-Olds T, Woodley R. | title=Bootstrapping the Gini coefficient of inequality | journal=Ecology | year=1987 | volume=68 | pages=1548-1551}}
*{{cite journal | author=Dorfman, Robert | title=A Formula for the Gini Coefficient | journal=The Review of Economics and Statistics | year=1979 | volume=61 | pages=146-149}} *{{cite journal | author=Dorfman, Robert | title=A Formula for the Gini Coefficient | journal=The Review of Economics and Statistics | year=1979 | volume=61 | pages=146-149}}
*{{cite journal | author=Gastwirth, Joseph L. | title=The Estimation of the Lorenz Curve and Gini Index | journal=The Review of Economics and Statistics | year=1972 | volume=54 | pages=306-316}}
*Gini, Corrado (1912). "Variabilità e mutabilità" Reprinted in Memorie di metodologica statistica (Ed. Pizetti E, Salvemini, T). Rome: Libreria Eredi Virgilio Veschi (1955).
*{{cite journal | author=Gini, Corrado | title=Measurement of Inequality and Incomes | journal=The Economic Journal | year=1921 | volume=31 | pages=124-126}}
*{{cite journal | author=Mills, Jeffrey A.; Zandvakili, Sourushe | title=Statistical Inference via Bootstrapping for Measures of Inequality | journal=Journal of Applied Econometrics | year=1997 | volume=12 | pages=133-150}} *{{cite journal | author=Mills, Jeffrey A.; Zandvakili, Sourushe | title=Statistical Inference via Bootstrapping for Measures of Inequality | journal=Journal of Applied Econometrics | year=1997 | volume=12 | pages=133-150}}
*{{cite journal | author=Brown, Malcolm | title=Using Gini-Style Indices to Evaluate the Spatial Patterns of Health Practitioners: Theoretical Considerations and an Application Based on Alberta Data | journal=Social Science Medicine | year=1994 | volume=38 | pages=1243-1256}} *{{cite journal | author=Morgan, James | title=The Anatomy of Income Distribution | journal=The Review of Economics and Statistics | year=1962 | volume=44 | pages=270-283 }}
*{{Cite paper | author=Xu, Kuan | title=How Has the Literature on Gini's Index Evolved in the Past 80 Years? | publisher=Department of Economics, Dalhousie University | date=January, 2004 | version= | url=http://economics.dal.ca/RePEc/dal/wparch/howgini.pdf | accessdate=2006-06-01 }}


==See also== ==See also==
Line 137: Line 146:
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ]


== External links == == External links ==
* United States Census Bureau List of Gini Coefficients by State for Families and Households
* ] : Gini Index calculated for all countries. * ] : Gini Index calculated for all countries.
* Comparison of Urban and Rural Areas' Gini Coefficients Within States * Comparison of Urban and Rural Areas' Gini Coefficients Within States
Line 147: Line 158:
* Software: * Software:
** computes the Gini Coefficient, plots the Lorenz curve, and computes many other measures of concentration for any dataset ** computes the Gini Coefficient, plots the Lorenz curve, and computes many other measures of concentration for any dataset
** Free Calculator: and (] and ]) for Atkinson, Gini, Hoover and Kullback-Leibler inequalities ** Free Calculator: and (] and ]) for Atkinson, Gini, and Hoover inequalities
** Users of the data analysis software can install the "ineq" package which allows for computation of a variety of inequality indices including Gini, Atkinson, Theil. ** Users of the data analysis software can install the "ineq" package which allows for computation of a variety of inequality indices including Gini, Atkinson, Theil.


Line 160: Line 171:
] ]
] ]
]
] ]
] ]
] ]
]
] ]
]
] ]
] ]
]
]
] ]

Revision as of 22:13, 18 May 2007

Graphical representation of the Gini coefficient

The Gini coefficient is a measure of inequality of a distribution of income. It is defined as a ratio with values between 0 and 1: the numerator is the area between the Lorenz curve of the distribution and the uniform (perfect) distribution line; the denominator is the area under the uniform distribution line. It was developed by the Italian statistician Corrado Gini and published in his 1912 paper "Variabilità e mutabilità" ("Variability and Mutability"). The Gini index is the Gini coefficient expressed as a percentage, and is equal to the Gini coefficient multiplied by 100. (The Gini coefficient is equal to half of the relative mean difference.)

The Gini coefficient is often used as an income inequality metric. (See that article for discussion of the social aspects of income inequality.) Here, 0 corresponds to perfect income equality (i.e. everyone has the same income) and 1 corresponds to perfect income inequality (i.e. one person has all the income, while everyone else has zero income).

The Gini coefficient can also be used to measure wealth inequality. This use requires that no one have a negative net wealth. It is also commonly used for the measurement of the discriminatory power of rating systems in credit risk management.

Calculation

The Gini coefficient is defined as a ratio of the areas on the Lorenz curve diagram. If the area between the line of perfect equality and Lorenz curve is A, and the area under the Lorenz curve is B, then the Gini coefficient is A/(A+B). Since A+B = 0.5, the Gini coefficient, G = A/(.5) = 2A = 1-2B. If the Lorenz curve is represented by the function Y = L(X), the value of B can be found with integration and:

G = 1 2 0 1 L ( X ) d X {\displaystyle G=1-2\,\int _{0}^{1}L(X)dX}

In some cases, this equation can be applied to calculate the Gini coefficient without direct reference to the Lorenz curve. For example:

  • For a population uniform on the values yi, i = 1 to n, indexed in non-decreasing order ( yiyi+1):
G = 1 n ( n + 1 2 ( Σ i = 1 n ( n + 1 i ) y i Σ i = 1 n y i ) ) {\displaystyle G={\frac {1}{n}}\left(n+1-2\left({\frac {\Sigma _{i=1}^{n}\;(n+1-i)y_{i}}{\Sigma _{i=1}^{n}y_{i}}}\right)\right)}
  • For a discrete probability function f(y), where yi, i = 1 to n, are the points with nonzero probabilities and which are indexed in increasing order ( yi < yi+1):
G = 1 Σ i = 1 n f ( y i ) ( S i 1 + S i ) S n {\displaystyle G=1-{\frac {\Sigma _{i=1}^{n}\;f(y_{i})(S_{i-1}+S_{i})}{S_{n}}}}
where:
S i = Σ j = 1 i f ( y j ) y j {\displaystyle S_{i}=\Sigma _{j=1}^{i}\;f(y_{j})\,y_{j}\,} and S 0 = 0 {\displaystyle S_{0}=0\,}
G = 1 1 μ 0 ( 1 F ( y ) ) 2 d y {\displaystyle G=1-{\frac {1}{\mu }}\int _{0}^{\infty }(1-F(y))^{2}dy}

Since the Gini coefficient is half the relative mean difference, it can also be calculated using formulas for the relative mean difference.

For a random sample S consisting of values yi, i = 1 to n, that are indexed in non-decreasing order ( yiyi+1), the statistic:

G ( S ) = 1 n 1 ( n + 1 2 ( Σ i = 1 n ( n + 1 i ) y i Σ i = 1 n y i ) ) {\displaystyle G(S)={\frac {1}{n-1}}\left(n+1-2\left({\frac {\Sigma _{i=1}^{n}\;(n+1-i)y_{i}}{\Sigma _{i=1}^{n}y_{i}}}\right)\right)}

is a consistent estimator of the population Gini coefficient, but is not, in general, unbiased. Like the relative mean difference, there does not exist a sample statistic that is in general an unbiased estimator of the population Gini coefficient. Confidence intervals for the population Gini coefficient can be calculated using bootstrap techniques.

Sometimes the entire Lorenz curve is not known, and only values at certain intervals are given. In that case, the Gini coefficient can be approximated by using various techniques for interpolating the missing values of the Lorenz curve. If ( X k , Yk ) are the known points on the Lorenz curve, with the X k indexed in increasing order ( X k - 1 < X k ), so that:

  • Xk is the cumulated proportion of the population variable, for k = 0,...,n, with X0 = 0, Xn = 1.
  • Yk is the cumulated proportion of the income variable, for k = 0,...,n, with Y0 = 0, Yn = 1.

If the Lorenz curve is approximated on each interval as a line between consecutive points, then the area B can be approximated with trapezoids and:

G 1 = 1 k = 1 n ( X k X k 1 ) ( Y k + Y k 1 ) {\displaystyle G_{1}=1-\sum _{k=1}^{n}(X_{k}-X_{k-1})(Y_{k}+Y_{k-1})}

is the resulting approximation for G. More accurate results can be obtained using other methods to approximate the area B, such as approximating the Lorenz curve with a quadratic function across pairs of intervals, or building an appropriately smooth approximation to the underlying distribution function that matches the known data. If the population mean and boundary values for each interval are also known, these can also often be used to improve the accuracy of the approximation.

Income Gini coefficients in the world

A complete listing is in list of countries by income equality; the article economic inequality discusses the social and policy aspects of income and asset inequality.

Gini coefficient, income distribution by country.
  < 0.25   0.25–0.29   0.30–0.34   0.35–0.39   0.40–0.44   0.45–0.49   0.50–0.54   0.55–0.59   ≥ 0.60   N/A

While most developed European nations tend to have Gini coefficients between 0.24 and 0.36, the United States Gini coefficient is above 0.4, indicating that the United States has greater inequality. Using the Gini can help quantify differences in welfare and compensation policies and philosophies. However it should be borne in mind that the Gini coefficient can be misleading when used to make political comparisons between large and small countries (see criticisms section).

Gini coefficients, income distribution over time for selected countries

Correlation with per-capita GDP

Poor countries (those with low per-capita GDP) have Gini coefficients that fall over the whole range from low (0.25) to high (0.71), while rich countries have generally intermediate Gini coefficient (under 0.40). Generally, the lowest Gini coefficients can be found in the Scandinavian countries, as well as the recently ex-socialist countries of Eastern Europe.

US income gini coefficients over time

Gini coefficients for the United States at various times, according to the US Census Bureau:

Some argue this rise corresponds to the lowering of the highest tax bracket, for example, from 70% in the 1960s to 35% by 2000. However, many other variables that could affect the Gini coefficient have changed during this period as well. For example, much technological progress has occurred, eliminating formerly middle-class factory jobs in favor of the service sector; additionally, the economy has shifted towards professions that require higher education.

Advantages of Gini coefficient as a measure of inequality

  • It can be used to compare income distributions across different population sectors as well as countries, for example the Gini coefficient for urban areas differs from that of rural areas in many countries (though the United States' urban and rural Gini coefficients are nearly identical).
  • It is sufficiently simple that it can be compared across countries and be easily interpreted. GDP statistics are often criticised as they do not represent changes for the whole population; the Gini coefficient demonstrates how income has changed for poor and rich. If the Gini coefficient is rising as well as GDP, poverty may not be improving for the majority of the population.
  • The Gini coefficient can be used to indicate how the distribution of income has changed within a country over a period of time, thus it is possible to see if inequality is increasing or decreasing.
  • The Gini coefficient satisfies four important principles:
    • Anonymity: it does not matter who the high and low earners are.
    • Scale independence: the Gini coefficient does not consider the size of the economy, the way it is measured, or whether it is a rich or poor country on average.
    • Population independence: it does not matter how large the population of the country is.
    • Transfer principle: if income (less than the difference), is transferred from a rich person to a poor person the resulting distribution is more equal.

Disadvantages of Gini coefficient as a measure of inequality

  • The Gini coefficient measured for a large economically diverse country will generally result in a much higher coefficient than each of its regions has individually. For this reason the scores calculated for individual countries within the EU are difficult to compare with the score of the entire US.
  • Comparing income distributions among countries may be difficult because benefits systems may differ. For example, some countries give benefits in the form of money while others give food stamps, which may not be counted as income in the Lorenz curve and therefore not taken into account in the Gini coefficient.
  • The measure will give different results when applied to individuals instead of households. When different populations are not measured with consistent definitions, comparison is not meaningful.
  • The Lorenz curve may understate the actual amount of inequality if richer households are able to use income more efficiently than lower income households. From another point of view, measured inequality may be the result of more or less efficient use of household incomes.
  • As for all statistics, there will be systematic and random errors in the data. The meaning of the Gini coefficient decreases as the data become less accurate. Also, countries may collect data differently, making it difficult to compare statistics between countries.
  • Economies with similar incomes and Gini coefficients can still have very different income distributions. This is because the Lorenz curves can have different shapes and yet still yield the same Gini coefficient. As an extreme example, an economy where half the households have no income, and the other half share income equally has a Gini coefficient of ½; but an economy with complete income equality, except for one wealthy household that has half the total income, also has a Gini coefficient of ½.
  • The Gini coefficient is used to measure income more than net worth, which can be misleading. For example, is Sweden egalitarian? Sweden has a low Gini coefficient for income distribution but a high Gini coefficient for wealth (0.1% of Swedish shareholders control 25% of all shares ).
  • Too often only the Gini coefficient is quoted without describing the proportions of the quantiles used for measurement. As with other inequality coefficients, the Gini coefficient is influenced by the granularity of the measurements. For example, five 20% quantiles (low granularity) will yield a lower Gini coefficient than twenty 5% quantiles (high granularity) taken from the same distribution.

As one result of this criticism, additionally to or in competition with the Gini coefficient entropy measures are frequently used (e.g. the Atkinson and Theil indices). These measures attempt to compare the distribution of resources by intelligent players in the market with a maximum entropy random distribution, which would occur if these players acted like non-intelligent particles in a closed system following the laws of statistical physics.

Notes

  1. Note that the calculation of the index for the United States was changed in 1992, resulting in an upwards shift of about 0.02 in the coefficient. Comparisons before and after that period may be misleading. (Data from the US Census Bureau.)

References

  • Anand, Sudhir (1983). Inequality and Poverty in Malaysia. New York: Oxford University Press.
  • Brown, Malcolm (1994). "Using Gini-Style Indices to Evaluate the Spatial Patterns of Health Practitioners: Theoretical Considerations and an Application Based on Alberta Data". Social Science Medicine. 38: 1243–1256.
  • Chakravarty, S. R. (1990). Ethical Social Index Numbers. New York: Springer-Verlag.
  • Dixon, PM, Weiner J., Mitchell-Olds T, Woodley R. (1987). "Bootstrapping the Gini coefficient of inequality". Ecology. 68: 1548–1551.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  • Dorfman, Robert (1979). "A Formula for the Gini Coefficient". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 61: 146–149.
  • Gastwirth, Joseph L. (1972). "The Estimation of the Lorenz Curve and Gini Index". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 54: 306–316.
  • Gini, Corrado (1912). "Variabilità e mutabilità" Reprinted in Memorie di metodologica statistica (Ed. Pizetti E, Salvemini, T). Rome: Libreria Eredi Virgilio Veschi (1955).
  • Gini, Corrado (1921). "Measurement of Inequality and Incomes". The Economic Journal. 31: 124–126.
  • Mills, Jeffrey A.; Zandvakili, Sourushe (1997). "Statistical Inference via Bootstrapping for Measures of Inequality". Journal of Applied Econometrics. 12: 133–150.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  • Morgan, James (1962). "The Anatomy of Income Distribution". The Review of Economics and Statistics. 44: 270–283.
  • Xu, Kuan (January, 2004). "How Has the Literature on Gini's Index Evolved in the Past 80 Years?" (PDF). Department of Economics, Dalhousie University. Retrieved 2006-06-01. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help); Cite journal requires |journal= (help)

See also

External links

  • Software:
    • Free Online Calculator computes the Gini Coefficient, plots the Lorenz curve, and computes many other measures of concentration for any dataset
    • Free Calculator: Online and downloadable scripts (Python and Lua) for Atkinson, Gini, and Hoover inequalities
    • Users of the R data analysis software can install the "ineq" package which allows for computation of a variety of inequality indices including Gini, Atkinson, Theil.
Categories: