Misplaced Pages

Parliamentary system: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 14:50, 19 July 2006 editInternationalIDEA (talk | contribs)89 editsm See also← Previous edit Latest revision as of 15:57, 17 December 2024 edit undoNyakase (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users, Rollbackers9,583 editsm Reverted edits by 78.211.46.247 (talk) (HG) (3.4.13)Tags: Huggle Rollback 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Form of government}}
]
{{Use dmy dates|date=December 2022}}
{{combi}}
{{Systems of government}}
|{{Legislature}}
{{Politics sidebar|Systems}}
|{{Executive}}
A '''parliamentary system''', or '''parliamentary democracy''', is a form of ] where the ] (chief executive) derives their ] legitimacy from their ability to command the support ("confidence") of a majority of the ], to which they are held accountable. This ] is usually, but not always, distinct from a ceremonial ]. This is in contrast to a presidential system, which features a president who is not fully accountable to the legislature, and cannot be replaced by a simple majority vote.
|}
A '''parliamentary system''', also known as '''parliamentarianism''' (and '''parliamentarism''' in U.S. English), is distinguished by the ] being dependent on the direct or indirect support of the ], often expressed through a ]. Hence, there is no clear-cut ] between the executive and ] branches, leading to criticism from some that they lack checks and balances found in a presidential ]. Parliamentarianism is praised, relative to ], for its flexibility and responsiveness to the public. It is faulted for its tendency to sometimes lead to unstable governments, as in the German ] and the ]. Parliamentary systems usually have a clear differentiation between the '']'' and the '']'', with the head of government being the ] or ], and the head of state often being an appointed ] with only minor or ceremonial powers. However, some parliamentary systems also have an elected ] with many reserve powers as the head of state, providing some balance to these systems.


Countries with parliamentary systems may be ], where a ] is the head of state while the head of government is almost always a ], or ], where a mostly ceremonial president is the head of state while the head of government is from the legislature. In a few countries, the head of government is also head of state but is elected by the legislature. In ] parliaments, the head of government is generally, though not always, a member of the ].
The term ''parliamentary system'' does not mean that a country is ruled by different parties in ] with each other. Such multi-party arrangements are usually the product of an ] known as ]. Parliamentary countries that use ] voting usually have governments composed of one party. The ], for instance, has had only one coalition government since ]. However, parliamentary systems of continental Europe do use proportional representation, so, outside the ], it can be said that PR voting systems and parliamentarianism go together.


Parliamentary democracy is the dominant ] in the ], ], and throughout the former ], with other users scattered throughout ] and ]. A similar system, called a ], is used by many ].
Parliamentarianism may also be heeded for governance in ]s. An example is the city of ], which has an executive council as a part of the parliamentary system.


==History==
==The features of a parliamentary system==
{{Further|History of parliamentarism}}


The first ]s date back to Europe in the Middle Ages. The earliest example of a parliament is disputed, especially depending how the term is defined.
The executive branch of a '''parliamentary government''' is typically a ], and headed by a prime minister who is considered the ''head of government,'' but parliamentarianism has also been practised with ]s. The prime minister and the ]s of the cabinet typically have their background in the parliament and may remain members thereof while serving in cabinet. The leader of the leading party, or group of parties, in the parliament is often appointed as the prime minister. In many countries, the cabinet, or single members thereof, can be removed by the parliament through a ]. In addition, the executive can often dissolve the parliament and call extraordinary elections. Under the parliamentary system the roles of ] and ] are more or less separated. In most parliamentary systems, the head of state is primarily a ceremonial position, often a ] or ], retaining duties that aren't politically divisive, such as appointments of ]. In many parliamentary systems, the head of state may have ]s which are usable in a crisis. In most cases however, such powers are (either by convention or by constitutional rule) only exercised upon the advice and approval of the head of government.


For example, the Icelandic ] consisting of prominent individuals among the free landowners of the various districts of the ] first gathered around the year 930 (it conducted its business orally, with no written record allowing an exact date).
Because the executive is directly related to the legislature, some argue the executive is actually more accountable than many ] presidential systems, as the executive, being linked to the legislative, can face an early election in the face of the aforementioned 'vote of no confidence'. In addition, because the executive is beholden to the ], it faces more direct questioning by opposition politicians than an executive would in a presidential system. It can also be argued that it's relatively easier to pass ] within a parliamentary system since the executive and the legislature are always controlled by the same party and since the executive has a greater ability to "snap the whip" and force wavering party members into alignment. Within ]s, the executive is often chosen independently from the legislature. If the executive is of a different party from those leading the legislature, then legislative activity can grind to a halt.


The first written record of a parliament, in particular in the sense of an assembly separate from the population called in presence of a King was 1188 Alfonso IX, King of Leon (Spain) convened the three states in the ].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.unesco.org/new/en/communication-and-information/memory-of-the-world/register/full-list-of-registered-heritage/registered-heritage-page-8/the-decreta-of-leon-of-1188-the-oldest-documentary-manifestation-of-the-european-parliamentary-system/|title=The Decreta of León of 1188 – The oldest documentary manifestation of the European parliamentary system|publisher=UNESCO Memory of the World|date=2013|access-date=21 May 2016|archive-date=24 June 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160624133501/http://www.unesco.org/new/en/communication-and-information/memory-of-the-world/register/full-list-of-registered-heritage/registered-heritage-page-8/the-decreta-of-leon-of-1188-the-oldest-documentary-manifestation-of-the-european-parliamentary-system/|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>John Keane: ''The Life and Death of Democracy'', London 2009, 169–176.</ref> The ] were the first parliament of Europe that officially obtained the power to pass legislation, apart from the custom.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Sánchez |first1=Isabel |title=La Diputació del General de Catalunya (1413-1479) |date=2004 |publisher=Institut d'Estudis Catalans |location=Barcelona |isbn=9788472837508 |page=92}}</ref> An early example of parliamentary government developed in today's Netherlands and Belgium during the ] (1581), when the sovereign, legislative and executive powers were taken over by the ] from the monarch, ].{{Citation needed|date=September 2016}} Significant developments ], in particular in the period 1707 to 1800 and its contemporary, the ], and later in Europe and elsewhere in the 19th and 20th centuries, with the expansion of like institutions, and beyond
Parliamentary systems vary as to the degree to which they have a formal written constitution and the degree to which that constitution describes the day to day working of the government. Also, depending upon the voting system, they vary as to the number of parties within the system and the dynamics between the parties. Relations between the central government and local governments vary in parliamentary systems; they may be ] or ]s.


In England, ] is remembered as one of the figures relevant later for convening two famous parliaments.<ref>{{cite book|last1=Jobson|first1=Adrian|title=The First English Revolution: Simon de Montfort, Henry III and the Barons' War|date=2012|publisher=Bloomsbury|isbn= 978-1-84725-226-5 |pages=173–4|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=9gHWamp-TLoC&pg=PA174|access-date=6 June 2020|archive-date=1 August 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200801012245/https://books.google.com/books?id=9gHWamp-TLoC&pg=PA174|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|title=Simon de Montfort: The turning point for democracy that gets overlooked |url= https://www.bbc.co.uk/news/magazine-30849472|access-date=19 January 2015|publisher=BBC|postscript=none|date=19 January 2015|archive-date=19 January 2015|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20150119092017/http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/magazine-30849472 |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|title=The January Parliament and how it defined Britain|url=https://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/politics/11355822/The-January-Parliament-and-how-it-defined-Britain.html|access-date=28 January 2015|newspaper=The Telegraph|date=20 January 2015|archive-date=23 January 2015|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150123010049/http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/politics/11355822/The-January-Parliament-and-how-it-defined-Britain.html|url-status=live}}</ref> ], in 1258, stripped the king of unlimited authority and the second, in 1265, included ].<ref name="dnb">{{cite DNB |last=Norgate |first=Kate |author-link=Kate Norgate |wstitle=Montfort, Simon of (1208?-1265)|volume=38 }}</ref> Later, in the 17th century, the ] pioneered some of the ideas and systems of ] culminating in the ] and passage of the ].<ref>{{cite book|editor1-last=Kopstein|editor1-first=Jeffrey|editor2-last=Lichbach|editor2-first=Mark|editor3-last=Hanson|editor3-first=Stephen E.|title=Comparative Politics: Interests, Identities, and Institutions in a Changing Global Order|date=2014|publisher=Cambridge University Press|isbn=978-1139991384|pages= 37–9|edition=4, revised|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=L2jwAwAAQBAJ&pg=PA38|quote=Britain pioneered the system of liberal democracy that has now spread in one form or another to most of the world's countries|access-date=6 June 2020|archive-date=30 June 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200630231313/https://books.google.com/books?id=L2jwAwAAQBAJ&pg=PA38|url-status=live}}</ref><ref name="refIIP">{{cite web|title=Constitutionalism: America & Beyond|url=http://www.ait.org.tw/infousa/zhtw/DOCS/Demopaper/dmpaper2.html |publisher=Bureau of International Information Programs (IIP), U.S. Department of State|access-date=30 October 2014|quote=The earliest, and perhaps greatest, victory for liberalism was achieved in England. The rising commercial class that had supported the Tudor monarchy in the 16th century led the revolutionary battle in the 17th, and succeeded in establishing the supremacy of Parliament and, eventually, of the House of Commons. What emerged as the distinctive feature of modern constitutionalism was not the insistence on the idea that the king is subject to law (although this concept is an essential attribute of all constitutionalism). This notion was already well established in the Middle Ages. What was distinctive was the establishment of effective means of political control whereby the rule of law might be enforced. Modern constitutionalism was born with the political requirement that representative government depended upon the consent of citizen subjects.... However, as can be seen through provisions in the 1689 Bill of Rights, the English Revolution was fought not just to protect the rights of property (in the narrow sense) but to establish those liberties which liberals believed essential to human dignity and moral worth. The "rights of man" enumerated in the English Bill of Rights gradually were proclaimed beyond the boundaries of England, notably in the American Declaration of Independence of 1776 and in the French Declaration of the Rights of Man in 1789.|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20141024130317/http://www.ait.org.tw/infousa/zhtw/DOCS/Demopaper/dmpaper2.html|archive-date=24 October 2014}}</ref>
==Advantages of a parliamentary system==


In the ], the monarch, in theory, chaired the cabinet and chose ministers. In practice, King ]'s inability to speak English led to the responsibility for chairing cabinet to go to the leading minister, literally the '']'' or first minister, ]. The gradual democratisation of parliament with the broadening of the voting franchise increased parliament's role in controlling government, and in deciding whom the king could ask to form a government. By the 19th century, the ] of 1832 led to parliamentary dominance, with its choice ''invariably'' deciding who was prime minister and the complexion of the government.<ref>{{cite web|title=The Institution of Prime Minister|url=https://history.blog.gov.uk/2012/01/01/the-institution-of-prime-minister/|publisher=Government of the United Kingdom|website = History of Government Blog|date=1 January 2012|first1= Andrew|last1= Blick |first2= George|last2= Jones|archive-date=10 March 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160310152512/https://history.blog.gov.uk/2012/01/01/the-institution-of-prime-minister/ |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|last1=Carter|first1=Byrum E.|title=Office of the Prime Minister|date=2015|orig-year=1955|publisher=Princeton University Press|isbn=9781400878260|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ez7WCgAAQBAJ|chapter=The Historical Development of the Office of Prime Minister|access-date=6 June 2020|archive-date=19 August 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200819062756/https://books.google.com/books?id=ez7WCgAAQBAJ|url-status=live}}</ref>
Some believe that it is easier to pass ] within a parliamentary system. This is because the executive branch is dependent upon the direct or indirect support of the legislative branch and often includes members of the ]. In a presidential system, the executive is often chosen independently from the legislature. If the executive and legislature in such a system include members entirely or predominantly from different ], then stalemate can occur. Former ] ] often faced problems in this regard, since the ] controlled ] for much of his tenure as President. That being said, presidents can also face problems from their own parties, as former ] ] did.


Other countries gradually adopted what came to be called the ] of government,<ref>{{cite web |date=2 December 2013 |title=How the Westminster Parliamentary System was exported around the World |url=http://www.cam.ac.uk/research/features/how-the-westminster-parliamentary-system-was-exported-around-the-world |access-date=16 December 2013 |publisher=University of Cambridge}}</ref> with an executive answerable to the lower house of a bicameral parliament, and exercising, in the name of the head of state, powers nominally vested in the head of state – hence the use of phrases such as ''Her Majesty's government'' (in constitutional monarchies) or ''His Excellency's government'' (in ]s).<ref>{{cite book |last1=Seidle |first1=F. Leslie |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=i6je60BF-3sC&pg=PA3 |title=Reforming parliamentary democracy |last2=Docherty |first2=David C. |date=2003 |publisher=McGill-Queen's University Press |isbn=9780773525085 |page=3}}</ref> Such a system became particularly prevalent in older British dominions, many of which had their constitutions enacted by the British parliament; such as Australia, New Zealand, Canada, the ] and the ].<ref>{{cite book |author1=Julian Go |title=Constitutionalism and political reconstruction |date=2007 |publisher=Brill |isbn=978-9004151741 |editor1-last=Arjomand |editor1-first=Saïd Amir |pages=92–94 |chapter=A Globalizing Constitutionalism?, Views from the Postcolony, 1945–2000 |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=kYmmnYKEvE0C&pg=PA94}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Johnston |first1=Douglas M. |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=dVuwCQAAQBAJ&pg=PA571 |title=The Historical Foundations of World Order |last2=Reisman |first2=W. Michael |date=2008 |publisher=Martinus Nijhoff Publishers |isbn=978-9047423935 |location=Leiden |page=571}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Fieldhouse |first1=David |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=nZHdAZDr-kYC&pg=PR21 |title=Settler Self-Government, 1840–1900: The Development of Representative and Responsible Government |last2=Madden |first2=Frederick |date=1990 |publisher=Greenwood Press |isbn=978-0-313-27326-1 |edition=1. publ. |location=New York |page=xxi}}</ref> Some of these parliaments were reformed from, or were initially developed as distinct from their original British model: the ], for instance, has since its inception more closely reflected the ] than the British ]; whereas since 1950 there is no upper house in New Zealand. Many of these countries such as ] and ] have severed institutional ties to Great Britain by becoming republics with their own ceremonial Presidents, but retain the Westminster system of government. The idea of parliamentary accountability and ] spread with these systems.<ref name=":5">{{Cite book |last1=Patapan |first1=Haig |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=JTg0ZTM8X4oC |title=Westminster Legacies: Democracy and Responsible Government in Asia and the Pacific |last2=Wanna |first2=John |last3=Weller |first3=Patrick Moray |date=2005 |publisher=UNSW Press |isbn=978-0-86840-848-4 |language=en}}</ref>
In addition to quicker legislative action, Parliamentarianism has attractive features for nations that are ethnically, racially, or ideologically divided. In a unipersonal presidential system, all executive power is concentrated in the president. In a parliamentary system, with a collegial executive, power is more divided. In the 1989 Lebanese ], in order to give Muslims greater political power, Lebanon moved from a ] with a strong president to a system more structurally similar to a classical parliamentarianism. Iraq similarly disdained a presidential system out of fears that such a system would be equivalent to Shiite domination; Afghanistan's minorities refused to go along with a presidency as strong as the ]s desired.


] and ] became increasingly prevalent in Europe in the years after ], partially imposed by the democratic victors,{{how|date=November 2019}} the United States, Great Britain and France, on the defeated countries and their successors, notably ] and the ]. Nineteenth-century ], the ] and ] had already made the parliamentarist demands of the ] and the emerging movement of ] increasingly impossible to ignore; these forces came to dominate many states that transitioned to parliamentarism, particularly in the ] where the ] and its centre-left allies dominated the government for several decades. However, the rise of ] in the 1930s put an end to parliamentary democracy in Italy and Germany, among others.
In the ''English Constitution'', ] praised parliamentarianism for producing serious debates, for allowing the change in power without an election, and for allowing elections at any time. Bagehot considered the four-year election rule of the United States to be unnatural.


After the ], the defeated ] were occupied by the victorious ]. In those countries occupied by the Allied democracies (the ], ], and ]) parliamentary constitutions were implemented, resulting in the ] and ] (now all of Germany) and the 1947 ]. The experiences of the war in the occupied nations where the legitimate democratic governments were allowed to return strengthened the public commitment to parliamentary principles; in ], a new constitution was written in 1953, while a long and acrimonious debate in Norway resulted in no changes being made to that country's ].
There is also a body of scholarship, associated with ], ], ], and ] that claims that parliamentarianism is less prone to authoritarian collapse. These scholars point out that since ], two-thirds of Third World countries establishing parliamentary governments successfully transitioned to democracy. By contrast, no Third World presidential system successfully transitioned to democracy without experiencing coups and other constitutional breakdowns. As Bruce Ackerman says of the thirty countries to have experimented with American checks and balances, “All of them, without exception, have succumbed to the nightmare one time or another, often repeatedly.”


==Characteristics==
A recent ] study found that parliamentary systems are associated with lower corruption.
{{More citations needed section|date=January 2016}}
{{Further|Parliamentary procedure}}
A parliamentary system may be either ], with two ] (or houses) or ], with just one parliamentary chamber. A bicameral parliament usually consists of a directly elected ] with the power to determine the executive government, and an ] which may be appointed or elected through a different mechanism from the lower house.


===Types===
==Criticisms of parliamentarianism==
Scholars of democracy such as ] distinguish two types of parliamentary democracies: the Westminster and Consensus systems.<ref>{{cite book| last=Lijphart |first=Arend |year=1999 |title=Patterns of democracy |location=New Haven |publisher=Yale University Press}}</ref>


====Westminster system====
A main criticism of many parliamentary systems is that the head of government cannot be directly voted on. Occasionally, an electorate will be surprised just by who is elevated to the premiership. In a presidential system, the president is directly chosen by the people, or by a set of electors directly chosen by the people, but in a parliamentary system the prime minister is elected by the party leadership.
] in ], United Kingdom. The ] originates from the ].]]
* The ] is usually found in the ] and countries which were influenced by the British political tradition.<ref>{{cite book|editor1-last=Arjomand|editor1-first=Saïd Amir|title=Constitutionalism and political reconstruction|date=2007|publisher=Brill|isbn=978-9004151741|pages=92–94|chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=kYmmnYKEvE0C&pg=PA94|author1=Julian Go|chapter=A Globalizing Constitutionalism?, Views from the Postcolony, 1945–2000|access-date=6 June 2020|archive-date=1 August 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200801015306/https://books.google.com/books?id=kYmmnYKEvE0C&lpg=PA93&pg=PA94|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|title=How the Westminster Parliamentary System was exported around the World|url=http://www.cam.ac.uk/research/features/how-the-westminster-parliamentary-system-was-exported-around-the-world|publisher=University of Cambridge|access-date=16 December 2013|date=2 December 2013|archive-date=16 December 2013|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20131216190945/http://www.cam.ac.uk/research/features/how-the-westminster-parliamentary-system-was-exported-around-the-world|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|last1=Seidle|first1=F. Leslie|last2=Docherty|first2=David C.|title=Reforming parliamentary democracy|date=2003|publisher=McGill-Queen's University Press|isbn=9780773525085|page=3|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=i6je60BF-3sC&pg=PA3|access-date=6 June 2020|archive-date=19 August 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200819121018/https://books.google.com/books?id=i6je60BF-3sC&pg=PA3|url-status=live}}</ref> These parliaments tend to have a more adversarial style of debate and the ] of parliament is more important than committees. Some parliaments in this model are elected using a ] (]), such as the United Kingdom, Canada, India and Malaysia, while others use some form of ], such as Ireland and New Zealand. The ] is elected using ], while the ] is elected using proportional representation through ]. Regardless of which system is used, the voting systems tend to allow the voter to vote for a named candidate rather than a ]. Most Westminster systems employ strict monism, where Ministers must be members of Parliament simultaneously; while some Westminster systems, such as ],<ref>{{Cite web|title=The Constitution of the People's Republic of Bangladesh|url=http://bdlaws.minlaw.gov.bd/act-details-367.html|access-date=2023-02-08|website=bdlaws.minlaw.gov.bd|at=Article 56}}</ref>{{secondary source needed|date=January 2024}} permit the appointment of extra-parliamentary Ministers, and others (such as ]) allow outsiders to be appointed to the Ministry through an appointed Upper House, although a majority of Ministers (which, by necessity, includes the Prime Minister) must come from within (the lower house of) Parliament.


====Consensus system====
Another major criticism comes from the relationship between the executive and legislative branches. Because there is a lack of obvious separation of power, some believe that a parliamentary system can place too much power in the ] entity, leading to the feeling that the ] or ] have little scope to administer checks or balances on the executive.
{{Unreferenced section|date=April 2022}}
] in ], Germany. The Consensus system is used in most Western European countries.]]
* The Western European parliamentary model (e.g., Spain, Germany) tends to have a more consensual debating system and usually has semi-circular debating chambers. Consensus systems have more of a tendency to use ] with ]s than the Westminster Model legislatures. The committees of these Parliaments tend to be more important than the ]. Most Western European countries do not employ strict monism, and allow extra-parliamentary ministers as a matter of course. The Netherlands, Slovakia and Sweden outright implement the principle of ] as a form of ], where Members of Parliament have to resign their place in Parliament upon being appointed (or elected) minister.


===Appointment of the head of government===
In the United Kingdom, the prime minister is traditionally thought of as the "]" of the cabinet. It has been alleged in ''The Economist'' and by former Member of Parliament ] that the prime minister's power has grown so much in recent years that he or she is now dominant over the government and that collegiality is no more. Rather than being "first among equals," the modern British prime minister is "like the moon among the stars," as ''The Economist'' once put it. "Instead of a healthy balance we have an executive who stands like an 800 lb. gorilla alongside a wizened legislature and judiciary." (Allen, 12)


Implementations of the parliamentary system can also differ as to how the prime minister and government are appointed and whether the government needs the explicit approval of the parliament, rather than just the absence of its disapproval. While most parliamentary systems such as India require the prime minister and other ministers to be a member of the legislature, in other countries like Canada and the United Kingdom this only exists as a convention, some other countries including Norway, Sweden and the Benelux countries require a sitting member of the legislature to resign such positions upon being appointed to the executive.
Although it is possible to have a powerful prime minister, as Britain has, or even a ], as Japan has, parliamentary systems are also sometimes unstable. Critics point to ], ], the ], and ] as examples of parliamentary systems where unstable coalitions, demanding minority parties, no confidence votes, and threats of no confidence votes, make or have made effective governance impossible. Defenders of parliamentarianism say that parliamentary instability is the result of ], political culture, and highly polarised electorates.


* ''' The head of state appoints a prime minister who will likely have majority support in parliament'''. While in the majority of cases prime ministers in the ] are the leaders of the largest party in parliament, technically the appointment of the prime minister is a prerogative exercised by the head of state (be it the monarch, the governor-general, or the president). This system is used in:
Although ] praised parliamentarianism for allowing an election to take place at any time, the lack of a definite election calendar can be abused. In some systems, such as the British, a ruling party can schedule elections when it feels that it is likely to do well, and so avoid elections at times of unpopularity. Thus, by wise timing of elections, in a parliamentary system a party can extend its rule for longer than is feasible in a functioning presidential system. In other systems, such as the Dutch, the ruling party or coalition has some flexibility in determining the election date.


** {{flag|Australia}}
==Parliamentarism and party formation==
** {{flag|Canada}}
Parties in parliamentary systems have had much tighter ideological cohesiveness than parties in presidential systems. It would be difficult for a parliamentary system to have a party like the ], which until the 1980s was a coalition of Southern conservative Protestants (']') and urban liberals with no single unified ideology. In a parliamentary system, a party such as this would typically splinter because, if in government, it may be unable to govern effectively. (Having splintered, though, the resulting parties might join in a governing coalition.)
** {{flag|India}}
** {{flag|Jamaica}}
** {{flag|Malaysia}}
** {{flag|New Zealand}}
** {{flag|United Kingdom}}
** {{flag|Denmark}}<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.ft.dk/da/folkestyret/regeringen/saadan-dannes-en-regering|title=Sådan dannes en regering / Folketinget|date=29 November 2016 |accessdate=31 July 2024}}</ref>
** {{flag|Portugal}}<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.parlamento.pt/sites/EN|title=The Assembleia da República as a body that exercises sovereign power / Folketinget| accessdate=16 September 2024}}</ref>
* ''' The head of state appoints a prime minister who must gain a vote of confidence within a set time.''' This system is used in:


** {{flag|Italy}}
==Countries with a parliamentary system of government==

], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ] , ], ], ], ], ], ], ],], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ], ].
* ''' The head of state appoints the leader of the political party holding a plurality of seats in parliament as prime minister'''. For example, in Greece, if no party has a majority, the leader of the party with a plurality of seats is given an ''exploratory mandate'' to receive the confidence of the parliament within three days. If said leader fails to obtain the confidence of parliament, then the leader of the ''second''-largest party is given the ''exploratory mandate''. If that fails, then the leader of the ''third''-largest political party is given the ''exploratory mandate'', and so on. This system is used in:

** {{flag|Greece}}

* ''' The head of state ''nominates'' a candidate for prime minister who is then submitted to parliament for approval before appointment.''' Example: Spain, where the King sends a proposal to the ] for approval. Also, Germany where under the ] (constitution) the ] votes on a candidate nominated by the federal president. In these cases,{{Citation needed|date=July 2019}} parliament can choose another candidate who then would be appointed by the head of state. This system is used in:

** {{flag|Estonia}}
** {{flag|Germany}}
** {{flag|Spain}}

* ''' Parliament ''nominates'' a candidate whom the head of state is constitutionally obliged to appoint as prime minister.''' Example: Japan, where the ] appoints the ] on the nomination of the ]. Also Ireland, where the ] appoints the ] on the nomination of ]. This system is used in:

** {{flag|Ireland}}
** {{flag|Japan}}
** {{flag|Thailand}}

* '''A public officeholder (other than the head of state or their representative) ''nominates'' a candidate, who, if approved by parliament, is appointed as prime minister.''' Example: Under the Swedish ], the power to appoint someone to form a government has been moved from the monarch to the Speaker of Parliament and the parliament itself. The speaker nominates a candidate, who is then elected to prime minister (''statsminister'') by the parliament if an absolute majority of the members of parliament does not vote against the candidate (i.e. they can be elected even if more members of parliament vote ''No'' than ''Yes).'' This system is used in:

** {{flag|Sweden}}

* '''Direct election by popular vote.''' Example: Israel, 1996–2001, where the prime minister was elected in a general election, with no regard to political affiliation, and whose procedure can also be described as of a ].<ref name="Pouvoirs">{{cite magazine |last=Duverger |first=Maurice |author-link=Maurice Duverger |date=September 1996 |title=Les monarchies républicaines |trans-title=The crowned republics |url=http://www.revue-pouvoirs.fr/IMG/pdf/78Pouvoirs_p107-120_monarchies_republicaines.pdf |language=fr |magazine=Pouvoirs, revue française d'études constitutionnelles et politiques |location=Paris |publisher=Éditions du Seuil |issn=0152-0768 |isbn=2-02-030123-7 |issue=78 |pages=107–120 |access-date=10 September 2016 |archive-date=1 October 2018 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20181001151614/https://revue-pouvoirs.fr/IMG/pdf/78Pouvoirs_p107-120_monarchies_republicaines.pdf |url-status=dead }}</ref><ref name="Forms">{{cite book |last1=Frosini |first1=Justin Orlando |year=2008 |editor-last=Ferrari |editor-first=Giuseppe Franco |title=Forms of State and Forms of Government |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=GFBPlYjuJYsC |publisher=Giuffrè Editore |pages=54–55 |isbn=9788814143885 |access-date=13 November 2016 |via=] |archive-date=19 August 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200819092351/https://books.google.com/books?id=GFBPlYjuJYsC |url-status=live }}</ref> This system was used in:

** {{flag|Israel}} (1996–2001)

===Power of dissolution and call for election===
Furthermore, there are variations as to what conditions exist (if any) for the government to have the right to dissolve the parliament:
* In some countries, especially those operating under a ], such as the United Kingdom, Denmark, Malaysia, Australia and New Zealand, the prime minister has the ''de facto'' power to call an election, at will. In Spain, the prime minister is the only person with the ''de jure'' power to call an election, granted by Article 115 of the ].
* In Israel, parliament may vote to dissolve itself in order to call an election, or the prime minister may call a snap election with presidential consent if his government is deadlocked. A non-passage of the budget automatically calls a snap election.
* Other countries only permit an election to be called in the event of a ] against the government, a supermajority vote in favour of an early election or a prolonged deadlock in parliament. These requirements can still be circumvented. For example, in Germany in 2005, ] deliberately allowed his government to lose a confidence motion, in order to call an early election.
* In Sweden, the government may call a snap election at will, but the newly elected ] is only elected to fill out the previous Riksdag's term. The last time this option was used was in ].
* In ], a general election is called if the ] fails to elect a new ] when his or her term ends. In January 2015, ] by ] to ] and oust rivals ] from power.
* In Italy the government has no power to call a snap election. A snap election can only be called by the ], following a consultation with the presidents of both houses of parliament.
* Norway is unique among parliamentary systems in that the ] always serves the whole of its four-year term.
* In Australia, under certain, unique conditions, the ] can request the ] to call for a ], whereby all rather than only half of the ], is dissolved – in effect electing all of the Parliament simultaneously.

The parliamentary system can be contrasted with a ] which operates under a stricter separation of powers, whereby the executive does not form part of—nor is appointed by—the parliamentary or legislative body. In such a system, parliaments or congresses do not select or dismiss heads of government, and governments cannot request an early dissolution as may be the case for parliaments (although the parliament may still be able to dissolve itself, as in the case of ]). There also exists the ] that draws on both presidential systems and parliamentary systems by combining a powerful president with an executive responsible to parliament: for example, the ].

Parliamentarianism may also apply to ] and ]s. An example is ] which has an executive council (Byråd) as a part of the parliamentary system. The ] are also parliamentary and which, as with the ], may hold early elections – this has only occurred with regards to the ] in ] and ].

===Anti-defection law===
{{redirect|Anti-defection law|the law in India|Anti-defection law (India)}}

A few parliamentary democratic nations such as ], Pakistan and Bangladesh have enacted laws that prohibit floor crossing or switching parties after the election. Under these laws, elected representatives will lose their seat in the parliament if they go against their party in votes.<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://prsindia.org/uploads/media/Note%20on%20Anti-Defection.pdf |title=The Anti-Defection Law – Intent and Impact Background Note for the Conference on Effective Legislatures |access-date=16 December 2019 |archive-date=19 August 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190819113945/http://www.prsindia.org/uploads/media/Note%20on%20Anti-Defection.pdf |url-status=live }}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.legalservicesindia.com/article/1937/Anti-defection-law-the-challenges.html|title=Anti-defection law the challenges|website=legalservicesindia.com|access-date=16 December 2019|archive-date=2 December 2019|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191202021958/http://www.legalservicesindia.com/article/1937/Anti-defection-law-the-challenges.html|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|url=http://nujslawreview.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/02/kartik-khanna-and-dhvani-shah.pdf|title=ANTI-DEFECTION LAW: A DEATH KNELL FOR PARLIAMENTARY DISSENT?|journal=NUJS Law Review|date=Mar 2012|access-date=15 May 2016|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160528062743/http://nujslawreview.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/02/kartik-khanna-and-dhvani-shah.pdf|archive-date=28 May 2016}}</ref>

In the UK parliament, a member is free to cross over to a different party. In Canada and Australia, there are no restraints on legislators switching sides.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://barandbench.com/anti-defection-laws-in-india-its-flaws-and-its-falls/|title= Anti-Defection Laws in India: Its flaws and its falls|date=1 August 2019}}</ref> In New Zealand, ] provides that MPs who switch parties or are expelled from their party may be expelled from Parliament at the request of their former party's leader.

=== Parliamentary sovereignty ===
{{Further|Parliamentary sovereignty}}
A few parliamentary democracies such as the ] and ] have weak or non-existent checks on the legislative power of their Parliaments,<ref>{{Cite web |date=27 October 2022 |title=UK Parliament glossary |url=https://www.parliament.uk/site-information/glossary/parliamentary-sovereignty/ |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220928161907/https://www.parliament.uk/site-information/glossary/parliamentary-sovereignty/ |archive-date=28 September 2022 |access-date=27 October 2022 |website=UK Parliament}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |date=20 January 2016 |title=Our system of government |url=https://www.parliament.nz/en/visit-and-learn/how-parliament-works/our-system-of-government/ |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221017113130/https://www.parliament.nz/en/visit-and-learn/how-parliament-works/our-system-of-government/ |archive-date=17 October 2022 |access-date=27 October 2022 |publisher=New Zealand Parliament}}</ref> where any newly approved Act shall take precedence over all prior Acts. All laws are equally unentrenched, wherein ] may not outright annul nor amend them, as frequently occurs in other parliamentary systems like ]. Whilst the head of state for both nations (], and or ]) has the de jure power to withhold ] to any bill passed by their Parliament, this check has not been exercised in Britain since the ].

Whilst both the UK and New Zealand have some Acts or parliamentary rules establishing ] or additional legislative procedures for certain legislation, such as previously with the ] (FTPA), these can be bypassed through the enactment of another that amends or ignores these supermajorities away, such as with the ] – bypassing the 2/3rd supermajority required for an early dissolution under the FTPA<ref>{{Cite web |date=26 November 2021 |title=Fixed-term Parliament Act 2011 |url=https://commonslibrary.parliament.uk/research-briefings/sn06111/ |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20221021190612/https://commonslibrary.parliament.uk/research-briefings/sn06111/ |archive-date=21 October 2022 |access-date=27 October 2022 |website=UK Parliament}}</ref> -, which enabled the early dissolution for the ].

=== Metrics ===
Parliamentarism metrics allow a quantitative comparison of the strength of parliamentary systems for individual countries. One parliamentarism metric is the Parliamentary Powers Index.<ref>{{Cite book|last1=Fish|first1=M. Steven|url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/handbook-of-national-legislatures/E069CD547EBAA4FE7D241E115C18664E|title=The Handbook of National Legislatures: A Global Survey|last2=Kroenig|first2=Matthew|date=2009|publisher=Cambridge University Press|isbn=978-0-521-51466-8|location=Cambridge|doi=10.1017/cbo9780511575655}}</ref>

==Advantages==
=== Adaptability ===
Parliamentary systems like that found in the United Kingdom are widely considered to be more flexible, allowing a rapid change in legislation and policy as long as there is a stable majority or coalition in parliament, allowing the government to have 'few legal limits on what it can do'<ref name = 0745-1253>{{Cite journal|last=Weaver|first=R. Kent|date=1985|title=Are Parliamentary Systems Better?|journal=The Brookings Review|volume=3|issue=4|pages=16–25|doi=10.2307/20079894|issn=0745-1253|jstor=20079894}}</ref> When combined with ], this system produces the classic "Westminster model" with the twin virtues of strong but responsive party government.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Norris|first=Pippa|s2cid=144867316|date=1995 |title= The Politics of Electoral Reform in Britain|journal= International Political Science Review|volume=16|issue=1|pages=65–78 |issn= 0192-5121 |jstor=1601169|doi=10.1177/019251219501600105}}</ref> This electoral system providing a strong majority in the House of Commons, paired with the ] results in a particularly powerful government able to provide change and 'innovate'.<ref name = 0745-1253/>

=== Scrutiny and accountability ===
The United Kingdom's fused power system is often noted to be advantageous with regard to accountability. The centralised government allows for more transparency as to where decisions originate from, this contrasts with the American system with Treasury Secretary ] saying "the president blames Congress, the Congress blames the president, and the public remains confused and disgusted with government in Washington".<ref>{{Cite book|url=http://archive.org/details/constitutionalre00sund_1|title=Constitutional reform and effective government|last=Sundquist|first=James L.|date=1992|publisher=Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution|others=Internet Archive}}</ref> Furthermore, ministers of the U.K. cabinet are subject to weekly Question Periods in which their actions/policies are scrutinised; no such regular check on the government exists in the U.S. system.

=== Distribution of power ===
A 2001 ] study found that parliamentary systems are associated with less corruption.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Lederman |first1=Daniel |title=Accountability and Corruption: Political Institutions Matter |series=Policy Research Working Papers |date=November 2001 |publisher=World Bank |page=27 |doi=10.1596/1813-9450-2708 |url=https://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/abs/10.1596/1813-9450-2708}}</ref>

=== Calling of elections ===
{{Unreferenced section|date=April 2022}}
{{Essay-like|section|date=January 2024}}

In his 1867 book '']'', ] praised parliamentary governments for producing serious debates, for allowing for a change in power without an election, and for allowing elections at any time. Bagehot considered ]s such as the four-year election rule for ] to be unnatural, as it can potentially allow a president who has disappointed the public with a dismal performance in the second year of his term to continue on until the end of his four-year term. Under a parliamentary system, a prime minister that has lost support in the middle of his term can be easily replaced by his own peers with a more popular alternative, as the Conservative Party in the UK did with successive prime ministers ], ], ], ], and ].

Although Bagehot praised parliamentary governments for allowing an election to take place at any time, the lack of a definite election calendar can be abused. Under some systems, such as the British, a ruling party can schedule elections when it believes that it is likely to retain power, and so avoid elections at times of unpopularity. (From 2011, election timing in the UK was partially fixed under the ], which was repealed by the ].) Thus, by a shrewd timing of elections, in a parliamentary system, a party can extend its rule for longer than is feasible in a presidential system. This problem can be alleviated somewhat by setting fixed dates for parliamentary elections, as is the case in several of Australia's state parliaments. In other systems, such as the Dutch and the Belgian, the ruling party or coalition has some flexibility in determining the election date. Conversely, flexibility in the timing of parliamentary elections can avoid periods of legislative gridlock that can occur in a fixed period presidential system. In any case, voters ultimately have the power to choose whether to vote for the ruling party or someone else.

== Disadvantages<!--'Anti-parliamentarianism' and 'Anti-parliamentarism' redirect here--> ==
===Incomplete separation of power===
{{Undue weight|date=January 2024|section|to=this section by making broad generalisations based solely on one citation, and looking solely at one country's parliamentary system}}

According to ], parliamentary systems in Europe have yielded very powerful heads of government which is rather what is often criticized about presidential systems. Fontaine compares United Kingdom's ] to the United States' ] noting the former head of government was much more powerful despite governing under a parliamentary system.<ref name=Fontaine2021>{{Cite news|title=Arturo Fontaine: "Si se estableciera el semipresidencialismo, a poco andar el pueblo sentiría que ha sido engañado"|url=https://www.emol.com/noticias/Nacional/2021/11/05/1037461/cronica-constitucional-arturo-fontaine-semipresidencialismo.html|last=Valenzuela Manguini|first=Álvaro|date=2021-11-05|access-date=2021-11-07|work=]|language=Spanish}}</ref> The rise to power of ] in Hungary has been claimed to show how parliamentary systems can be subverted.<ref name=Fontaine2021/> The situation in Hungary was according to Fontaine allowed by the deficient separation of powers that characterises parliamentary and semi-presidential systems.<ref name=Fontaine2021/> Once ] of the seats in Parliament in a single election, a ] large enough to amend the Hungarian constitution, there was no institution that was able to balance the concentration of power.<ref name=Fontaine2021/> In a presidential system it would require at least two separate elections to create the same effect; the presidential election, and the legislative election, and that the president's party has the legislative supermajority required for constitutional amendments. Safeguards against this situation implementable in both systems include the establishment of an upper house or a requirement for external ratification of constitutional amendments such as a ]. Fontaine also notes as a warning example of the flaws of parliamentary systems that if the United States had a parliamentary system, ], as head of government, could have dissolved the ].<ref name=Fontaine2021/>

=== Legislative flip-flopping ===
{{Undue weight|date=January 2024|section|to=by making broad generalisations but citing only one authority}}

The ability for strong parliamentary governments to push legislation through with the ease of fused power systems such as in the United Kingdom, whilst positive in allowing rapid adaptation when necessary e.g. the nationalisation of services during the world wars, in the opinion of some commentators does have its drawbacks. For instance, the flip-flopping of legislation back and forth as the majority in parliament changed between the Conservatives and Labour over the period 1940–1980, contesting over the nationalisation and privatisation of the British Steel Industry resulted in major instability for the British steel sector.<ref name = 0745-1253/>

=== ] ===
{{Undue weight|date=January 2024|section|to=by making broad generalisations but citing only one authority}}

In R. Kent Weaver's book ''Are Parliamentary Systems Better?'', he writes that an advantage of presidential systems is their ability to allow and accommodate more diverse viewpoints. He states that because "legislators are not compelled to vote against their constituents on matters of local concern, parties can serve as organizational and roll-call cuing vehicles without forcing out dissidents."<ref name = 0745-1253/>

=== Democratic unaccountability ===
{{Essay-like|section|date=January 2024}}
{{Original research section|reason=Nothing in the citation supports the statements in this section.|date=January 2024}}

All current parliamentary democracies see the indirect election or appointment of their head of government. As a result, the electorate has limited power to remove or install the person or party wielding the most power. Although ] may enable the party of the prime minister to be removed or empowered, this can be at the expense of voters first preferences in the many parliamentary systems utilising ], or having no effect in dislodging those parties who consistently form part of a coalition government, as with the current ] ] and his party the ]'s 4 terms in office, despite their peak support reaching only ].<ref>{{Cite news |last=Henley |first=Jon |date=14 December 2021 |title='Teflon' Mark Rutte set for fourth Dutch term after record-breaking talks |work=The Guardian |url=https://www.theguardian.com/world/2021/dec/14/teflon-mark-rutte-fourth-dutch-term-record-breaking-talks-government-coalition |url-access=registration |access-date=27 October 2022}}</ref>

==Countries==
{{main|List of countries by system of government#Parliamentary systems}}

===Africa===
{| class="wikitable"
|-
! Country !! Connection between the legislature and the executive
|-
| {{flagu|Botswana}} || ] elects the ] who appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Ethiopia}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Lesotho}} || ] determines the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Mauritius}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Somalia}} || ] elects the ] who appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|South Africa}} || ] elects the ] who appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Togo}} ||
] elects the ] who appoints the ]
|}

===Americas===
]]]
]]]

{| class="wikitable"
|-
! width=230pt|Country !! Connection between the legislature and the executive
|-
| {{flagu|Antigua and Barbuda}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|The Bahamas}}|| Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Barbados}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Belize}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Canada}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Dominica}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Grenada}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Jamaica}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Saint Kitts and Nevis}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Saint Lucia}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Saint Vincent and the Grenadines}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Suriname}} ||] elects the ], who appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Trinidad and Tobago}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
|}

===Asia===
]]]
], parliament building of Bangladesh]]
], parliament building of India]]
]]]
] of Israel in ]]]
]]]
{| class="wikitable"
|-
! width=130pt|Country !! Connection between the legislature and the executive
|-
|{{flagu|Armenia}}
|] appoints and (no sooner than one year) can dismiss through the ] the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Bangladesh}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Bhutan}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Cambodia}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Republic of China|1928}} (Taiwan)||
* 1947 Constitution: The ] approves the ] in which the premier is nominated and appointed by the president, with the consent of the Legislative Yuan.
* 2005 Amendments: The ] approves the ] in which the premier is appointed by the president. The Legislative Yuan may vote for motion of no confidence.
|-
| {{flagu|Georgia}} ||The ] is nominated by a political party that has secured the best results in the parliamentary election. The nominee must be approved by the ] and then formally appointed by the ]. The Prime Minister then appoints the ].
|-
| {{flagu|India}} ||] appoints the leader of the political party or ] that has the support of a majority in the ] as ], who then forms the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Iraq}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Israel}} || A member of the ] that has the best chance of forming a coalition is given a mandate to do so by the ]. On success, they are appointed as the ]. The Prime Minister then appoints the ].
|-
| {{flagu|Japan}} || ] nominates the ] who appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Kuwait}} || ] approves the Crown Prince who appoints the ] who appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Laos}} || ] elects the ] who nominates the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Lebanon}} || Maronite Christian president is elected by the ]. He appoints the Prime Minister (a Sunni Muslim) and the cabinet. The Parliament thereafter approves the ] through a vote of confidence (a simple majority).
|-
| {{flagu|Malaysia}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister.
|-
| {{flagu|Myanmar}} || ], by an ], elects the ] who forms the ]. However, Myanmar is currently under the rule of the ], which assumed power by ]
|-
| {{flagu|Nepal}} || ] elects the ] who, by turn, appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Pakistan}} || ] elects the ] who has majority support of members of ]. ] is appointed by ] on advice of Prime Minister.
|-
| {{flagu|Singapore}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister.
|-
| {{flagu|Thailand}} || The ] appoints the MP or individual nominated by in the ] (usually the leader of the largest party or coalition) as ], who forms the ].
|-
| {{flagu|Vietnam}} || ] elects the ] and ] who forms the ].
|-
|}

===Europe===
]
], the lower chamber of Spanish Parliament]]

{| class="wikitable"
|-
! Country !! Connection between the legislature and the executive
|-
| {{flagu|Albania}} || The ] nominates the candidate chosen by the party or coalition which holds a majority in the ]. The Parliament then approves the ]. If the nomination is rejected by the Parliament, another candidate is chosen by the President within 10 days.
|-
| {{flagu|Andorra}} ||
|-
| {{flagu|Austria}} ||
|-
| {{flagu|Belgium}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Bulgaria}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Croatia}} || ] approves ] and the ] nominated by him/her.
|-
| {{flagu|Czech Republic}} || ] appoints usually the leader of the largest party or coalition in the ] as Prime Minister, who forms the ]. The Prime Minister must gain a ] by the ].
|-
| {{flagu|Denmark}} || The ] appoints, based on recommendations from the leaders of the parties in ], the cabinet leader who is most likely to successfully assemble a ] which will not be disapproved by a majority in ].
|-
| {{flagu|Estonia}} || ] elects the ] candidate nominated by the ] (normally this candidate is the leader of the parliamentary coalition of parties). The ] is later appointed by the President of the Republic under proposal of the approved Prime Minister candidate. The Riigikogu may remove the Prime Minister and any other member of the government through a motion of no confidence.
|-
| {{flagu|Finland}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Germany}} ||] elects the ] (after nomination from the ]), who forms the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Greece}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Hungary}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Iceland}} || The ] appoints and discharges the ]. Ministers can not even resign without being discharged by ].
|-
| {{flagu|Ireland}} || ] nominates the ], who is then appointed by the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Italy}} || ] grants and revokes its confidence in the ], appointed by the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Kosovo}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Latvia}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Luxembourg}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Malta}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Moldova}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Montenegro}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Netherlands}} || ] can dismiss the ] through a ]
|-
| {{nowrap|{{flagu|North Macedonia}}}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Norway}} || The ] appoints the MP leading the largest party or coalition in ] as ], who forms the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Poland}} ||
|-
| {{flagu|Portugal}} ||After the ] for the ] or the resignation of the previous government, the ] listens to the parties in the Assembly of the Republic and invites someone to form a government, usually the leader of the biggest party. Then the president swears in the ] and the Government.
|-
| {{flagu|San Marino}} ||
|-
| {{flagu|Serbia}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Slovakia}} || ] approves the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Slovenia}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Spain}} || ] elects the ], who forms the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Sweden}} || The ] elects the ], who in turn appoints the other members of the ]
|-
| {{nowrap|{{flagu|United Kingdom}}}} || The Leader, almost invariably a ] (MP) and of the political party which commands or is likely to command the confidence of a majority of the ], is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints members of the ] on the nomination and advice of the Prime Minister.
|}

===Oceania===
]]]
]]]

{| class="wikitable"
|-
! Country !! Connection between the legislature and the executive
|-
| {{flagu|Australia}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|New Zealand}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Papua New Guinea}} || Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the ] is appointed ] by the ], who then appoints the ] on the advice of the Prime Minister
|-
| {{flagu|Samoa}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
| {{flagu|Vanuatu}} || ] appoints the ]
|-
|}


==See also== == See also ==
* ]
*]
* ]
*]
* ]
*]
* ]
*]
* ]
*]
* ]
*] (on 18th century Parliamentarism)
*] * ]
* ]
*]
*] * ]
* ]


==References==
* from
{{reflist}}
* from the
* Expert maintained site providing encylopedia on Electoral Systems and Management, country by country data, a library of electoral materials, latest election news, and the oportunity to submit questions to a network of electoral experts


== External links ==
{{Legislative systems}}
{{wikiquote}}


{{Government}}
]
{{Authority control}}
]
]


{{DEFAULTSORT:Parliamentary System}}
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]

Latest revision as of 15:57, 17 December 2024

Form of government

World's states coloured by systems of government:
Parliamentary systems: Head of government is elected or nominated by and accountable to the legislature   Constitutional monarchy with a ceremonial monarch   Parliamentary republic with a ceremonial president   Parliamentary republic with an executive president
Presidential system: Head of government (president) is popularly elected and independent of the legislature   Presidential republic
Hybrid systems:   Semi-presidential republic: Executive president is independent of the legislature; head of government is appointed by the president and is accountable to the legislature   Assembly-independent republic: Head of government (president or directory) is elected by the legislature, but is not accountable to it
Other systems:   Theocratic republic: Supreme Leader holds significant executive and legislative power   Semi-constitutional monarchy: Monarch holds significant executive or legislative power   Absolute monarchy: Monarch has unlimited power   One-party state: Power is constitutionally linked to a single political party   Military junta: Committee of military leaders controls the government; constitutional provisions are suspended   Provisional government: No constitutionally defined basis to current regime   Dependent territories or places without governments
Note: this chart represents the de jure systems of government, not the de facto degree of democracy.
Part of the Politics series
Politics
Primary topics
Political systems
Academic disciplines
Public administration
Policy
Government branches
Related topics
Subseries
icon Politics portal

A parliamentary system, or parliamentary democracy, is a form of government where the head of government (chief executive) derives their democratic legitimacy from their ability to command the support ("confidence") of a majority of the legislature, to which they are held accountable. This head of government is usually, but not always, distinct from a ceremonial head of state. This is in contrast to a presidential system, which features a president who is not fully accountable to the legislature, and cannot be replaced by a simple majority vote.

Countries with parliamentary systems may be constitutional monarchies, where a monarch is the head of state while the head of government is almost always a member of parliament, or parliamentary republics, where a mostly ceremonial president is the head of state while the head of government is from the legislature. In a few countries, the head of government is also head of state but is elected by the legislature. In bicameral parliaments, the head of government is generally, though not always, a member of the lower house.

Parliamentary democracy is the dominant form of government in the European Union, Oceania, and throughout the former British Empire, with other users scattered throughout Africa and Asia. A similar system, called a council–manager government, is used by many local governments in the United States.

History

Further information: History of parliamentarism

The first parliaments date back to Europe in the Middle Ages. The earliest example of a parliament is disputed, especially depending how the term is defined.

For example, the Icelandic Althing consisting of prominent individuals among the free landowners of the various districts of the Icelandic Commonwealth first gathered around the year 930 (it conducted its business orally, with no written record allowing an exact date).

The first written record of a parliament, in particular in the sense of an assembly separate from the population called in presence of a King was 1188 Alfonso IX, King of Leon (Spain) convened the three states in the Cortes of León. The Corts of Catalonia were the first parliament of Europe that officially obtained the power to pass legislation, apart from the custom. An early example of parliamentary government developed in today's Netherlands and Belgium during the Dutch revolt (1581), when the sovereign, legislative and executive powers were taken over by the States General of the Netherlands from the monarch, King Philip II of Spain. Significant developments Kingdom of Great Britain, in particular in the period 1707 to 1800 and its contemporary, the Parliamentary System in Sweden between 1721 and 1772, and later in Europe and elsewhere in the 19th and 20th centuries, with the expansion of like institutions, and beyond

In England, Simon de Montfort is remembered as one of the figures relevant later for convening two famous parliaments. The first, in 1258, stripped the king of unlimited authority and the second, in 1265, included ordinary citizens from the towns. Later, in the 17th century, the Parliament of England pioneered some of the ideas and systems of liberal democracy culminating in the Glorious Revolution and passage of the Bill of Rights 1689.

In the Kingdom of Great Britain, the monarch, in theory, chaired the cabinet and chose ministers. In practice, King George I's inability to speak English led to the responsibility for chairing cabinet to go to the leading minister, literally the prime or first minister, Robert Walpole. The gradual democratisation of parliament with the broadening of the voting franchise increased parliament's role in controlling government, and in deciding whom the king could ask to form a government. By the 19th century, the Great Reform Act of 1832 led to parliamentary dominance, with its choice invariably deciding who was prime minister and the complexion of the government.

Other countries gradually adopted what came to be called the Westminster system of government, with an executive answerable to the lower house of a bicameral parliament, and exercising, in the name of the head of state, powers nominally vested in the head of state – hence the use of phrases such as Her Majesty's government (in constitutional monarchies) or His Excellency's government (in parliamentary republics). Such a system became particularly prevalent in older British dominions, many of which had their constitutions enacted by the British parliament; such as Australia, New Zealand, Canada, the Irish Free State and the Union of South Africa. Some of these parliaments were reformed from, or were initially developed as distinct from their original British model: the Australian Senate, for instance, has since its inception more closely reflected the US Senate than the British House of Lords; whereas since 1950 there is no upper house in New Zealand. Many of these countries such as Trinidad and Tobago and Barbados have severed institutional ties to Great Britain by becoming republics with their own ceremonial Presidents, but retain the Westminster system of government. The idea of parliamentary accountability and responsible government spread with these systems.

Democracy and parliamentarianism became increasingly prevalent in Europe in the years after World War I, partially imposed by the democratic victors, the United States, Great Britain and France, on the defeated countries and their successors, notably Germany's Weimar Republic and the First Austrian Republic. Nineteenth-century urbanisation, the Industrial Revolution and modernism had already made the parliamentarist demands of the Radicals and the emerging movement of social democrats increasingly impossible to ignore; these forces came to dominate many states that transitioned to parliamentarism, particularly in the French Third Republic where the Radical Party and its centre-left allies dominated the government for several decades. However, the rise of Fascism in the 1930s put an end to parliamentary democracy in Italy and Germany, among others.

After the Second World War, the defeated fascist Axis powers were occupied by the victorious Allies. In those countries occupied by the Allied democracies (the United States, United Kingdom, and France) parliamentary constitutions were implemented, resulting in the parliamentary constitutions of Italy and West Germany (now all of Germany) and the 1947 Constitution of Japan. The experiences of the war in the occupied nations where the legitimate democratic governments were allowed to return strengthened the public commitment to parliamentary principles; in Denmark, a new constitution was written in 1953, while a long and acrimonious debate in Norway resulted in no changes being made to that country's strongly entrenched democratic constitution.

Characteristics

This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (January 2016) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
Further information: Parliamentary procedure

A parliamentary system may be either bicameral, with two chambers of parliament (or houses) or unicameral, with just one parliamentary chamber. A bicameral parliament usually consists of a directly elected lower house with the power to determine the executive government, and an upper house which may be appointed or elected through a different mechanism from the lower house.

Types

Scholars of democracy such as Arend Lijphart distinguish two types of parliamentary democracies: the Westminster and Consensus systems.

Westminster system

The Palace of Westminster in London, United Kingdom. The Westminster system originates from the British Houses of Parliament.
  • The Westminster system is usually found in the Commonwealth of Nations and countries which were influenced by the British political tradition. These parliaments tend to have a more adversarial style of debate and the plenary session of parliament is more important than committees. Some parliaments in this model are elected using a plurality voting system (first past the post), such as the United Kingdom, Canada, India and Malaysia, while others use some form of proportional representation, such as Ireland and New Zealand. The Australian House of Representatives is elected using instant-runoff voting, while the Senate is elected using proportional representation through single transferable vote. Regardless of which system is used, the voting systems tend to allow the voter to vote for a named candidate rather than a closed list. Most Westminster systems employ strict monism, where Ministers must be members of Parliament simultaneously; while some Westminster systems, such as Bangladesh, permit the appointment of extra-parliamentary Ministers, and others (such as Jamaica) allow outsiders to be appointed to the Ministry through an appointed Upper House, although a majority of Ministers (which, by necessity, includes the Prime Minister) must come from within (the lower house of) Parliament.

Consensus system

This section does not cite any sources. Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (April 2022) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
The Reichstag Building in Berlin, Germany. The Consensus system is used in most Western European countries.
  • The Western European parliamentary model (e.g., Spain, Germany) tends to have a more consensual debating system and usually has semi-circular debating chambers. Consensus systems have more of a tendency to use proportional representation with open party lists than the Westminster Model legislatures. The committees of these Parliaments tend to be more important than the plenary chamber. Most Western European countries do not employ strict monism, and allow extra-parliamentary ministers as a matter of course. The Netherlands, Slovakia and Sweden outright implement the principle of dualism as a form of separation of powers, where Members of Parliament have to resign their place in Parliament upon being appointed (or elected) minister.

Appointment of the head of government

Implementations of the parliamentary system can also differ as to how the prime minister and government are appointed and whether the government needs the explicit approval of the parliament, rather than just the absence of its disapproval. While most parliamentary systems such as India require the prime minister and other ministers to be a member of the legislature, in other countries like Canada and the United Kingdom this only exists as a convention, some other countries including Norway, Sweden and the Benelux countries require a sitting member of the legislature to resign such positions upon being appointed to the executive.

  • The head of state appoints a prime minister who will likely have majority support in parliament. While in the majority of cases prime ministers in the Westminster system are the leaders of the largest party in parliament, technically the appointment of the prime minister is a prerogative exercised by the head of state (be it the monarch, the governor-general, or the president). This system is used in:
  • The head of state appoints the leader of the political party holding a plurality of seats in parliament as prime minister. For example, in Greece, if no party has a majority, the leader of the party with a plurality of seats is given an exploratory mandate to receive the confidence of the parliament within three days. If said leader fails to obtain the confidence of parliament, then the leader of the second-largest party is given the exploratory mandate. If that fails, then the leader of the third-largest political party is given the exploratory mandate, and so on. This system is used in:
  • The head of state nominates a candidate for prime minister who is then submitted to parliament for approval before appointment. Example: Spain, where the King sends a proposal to the Congress of Deputies for approval. Also, Germany where under the German Basic Law (constitution) the Bundestag votes on a candidate nominated by the federal president. In these cases, parliament can choose another candidate who then would be appointed by the head of state. This system is used in:
  • A public officeholder (other than the head of state or their representative) nominates a candidate, who, if approved by parliament, is appointed as prime minister. Example: Under the Swedish Instrument of Government (1974), the power to appoint someone to form a government has been moved from the monarch to the Speaker of Parliament and the parliament itself. The speaker nominates a candidate, who is then elected to prime minister (statsminister) by the parliament if an absolute majority of the members of parliament does not vote against the candidate (i.e. they can be elected even if more members of parliament vote No than Yes). This system is used in:
  • Direct election by popular vote. Example: Israel, 1996–2001, where the prime minister was elected in a general election, with no regard to political affiliation, and whose procedure can also be described as of a semi-parliamentary system. This system was used in:

Power of dissolution and call for election

Furthermore, there are variations as to what conditions exist (if any) for the government to have the right to dissolve the parliament:

  • In some countries, especially those operating under a Westminster system, such as the United Kingdom, Denmark, Malaysia, Australia and New Zealand, the prime minister has the de facto power to call an election, at will. In Spain, the prime minister is the only person with the de jure power to call an election, granted by Article 115 of the Constitution.
  • In Israel, parliament may vote to dissolve itself in order to call an election, or the prime minister may call a snap election with presidential consent if his government is deadlocked. A non-passage of the budget automatically calls a snap election.
  • Other countries only permit an election to be called in the event of a vote of no confidence against the government, a supermajority vote in favour of an early election or a prolonged deadlock in parliament. These requirements can still be circumvented. For example, in Germany in 2005, Gerhard Schröder deliberately allowed his government to lose a confidence motion, in order to call an early election.
  • In Sweden, the government may call a snap election at will, but the newly elected Riksdag is only elected to fill out the previous Riksdag's term. The last time this option was used was in 1958.
  • In Greece, a general election is called if the Parliament fails to elect a new head of state when his or her term ends. In January 2015, this constitutional provision was exploited by Syriza to trigger a snap election, win it and oust rivals New Democracy from power.
  • In Italy the government has no power to call a snap election. A snap election can only be called by the head of state, following a consultation with the presidents of both houses of parliament.
  • Norway is unique among parliamentary systems in that the Storting always serves the whole of its four-year term.
  • In Australia, under certain, unique conditions, the prime minister can request the Governor General to call for a double dissolution, whereby all rather than only half of the Senate, is dissolved – in effect electing all of the Parliament simultaneously.

The parliamentary system can be contrasted with a presidential system which operates under a stricter separation of powers, whereby the executive does not form part of—nor is appointed by—the parliamentary or legislative body. In such a system, parliaments or congresses do not select or dismiss heads of government, and governments cannot request an early dissolution as may be the case for parliaments (although the parliament may still be able to dissolve itself, as in the case of Cyprus). There also exists the semi-presidential system that draws on both presidential systems and parliamentary systems by combining a powerful president with an executive responsible to parliament: for example, the French Fifth Republic.

Parliamentarianism may also apply to regional and local governments. An example is Oslo which has an executive council (Byråd) as a part of the parliamentary system. The devolved nations of the United Kingdom are also parliamentary and which, as with the UK Parliament, may hold early elections – this has only occurred with regards to the Northern Ireland Assembly in 2017 and 2022.

Anti-defection law

"Anti-defection law" redirects here. For the law in India, see Anti-defection law (India).

A few parliamentary democratic nations such as India, Pakistan and Bangladesh have enacted laws that prohibit floor crossing or switching parties after the election. Under these laws, elected representatives will lose their seat in the parliament if they go against their party in votes.

In the UK parliament, a member is free to cross over to a different party. In Canada and Australia, there are no restraints on legislators switching sides. In New Zealand, waka-jumping legislation provides that MPs who switch parties or are expelled from their party may be expelled from Parliament at the request of their former party's leader.

Parliamentary sovereignty

Further information: Parliamentary sovereignty

A few parliamentary democracies such as the United Kingdom and New Zealand have weak or non-existent checks on the legislative power of their Parliaments, where any newly approved Act shall take precedence over all prior Acts. All laws are equally unentrenched, wherein judicial review may not outright annul nor amend them, as frequently occurs in other parliamentary systems like Germany. Whilst the head of state for both nations (Monarch, and or Governor General) has the de jure power to withhold assent to any bill passed by their Parliament, this check has not been exercised in Britain since the 1708 Scottish Militia Bill.

Whilst both the UK and New Zealand have some Acts or parliamentary rules establishing supermajorities or additional legislative procedures for certain legislation, such as previously with the Fixed-term Parliaments Act 2011 (FTPA), these can be bypassed through the enactment of another that amends or ignores these supermajorities away, such as with the Early Parliamentary General Election Act 2019 – bypassing the 2/3rd supermajority required for an early dissolution under the FTPA -, which enabled the early dissolution for the 2019 general election.

Metrics

Parliamentarism metrics allow a quantitative comparison of the strength of parliamentary systems for individual countries. One parliamentarism metric is the Parliamentary Powers Index.

Advantages

Adaptability

Parliamentary systems like that found in the United Kingdom are widely considered to be more flexible, allowing a rapid change in legislation and policy as long as there is a stable majority or coalition in parliament, allowing the government to have 'few legal limits on what it can do' When combined with first-past-the-post voting, this system produces the classic "Westminster model" with the twin virtues of strong but responsive party government. This electoral system providing a strong majority in the House of Commons, paired with the fused power system results in a particularly powerful government able to provide change and 'innovate'.

Scrutiny and accountability

The United Kingdom's fused power system is often noted to be advantageous with regard to accountability. The centralised government allows for more transparency as to where decisions originate from, this contrasts with the American system with Treasury Secretary C. Douglas Dillon saying "the president blames Congress, the Congress blames the president, and the public remains confused and disgusted with government in Washington". Furthermore, ministers of the U.K. cabinet are subject to weekly Question Periods in which their actions/policies are scrutinised; no such regular check on the government exists in the U.S. system.

Distribution of power

A 2001 World Bank study found that parliamentary systems are associated with less corruption.

Calling of elections

This section does not cite any sources. Please help improve this section by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (April 2022) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
This section is written like a personal reflection, personal essay, or argumentative essay that states a Misplaced Pages editor's personal feelings or presents an original argument about a topic. Please help improve it by rewriting it in an encyclopedic style. (January 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

In his 1867 book The English Constitution, Walter Bagehot praised parliamentary governments for producing serious debates, for allowing for a change in power without an election, and for allowing elections at any time. Bagehot considered fixed-term elections such as the four-year election rule for presidents of the United States to be unnatural, as it can potentially allow a president who has disappointed the public with a dismal performance in the second year of his term to continue on until the end of his four-year term. Under a parliamentary system, a prime minister that has lost support in the middle of his term can be easily replaced by his own peers with a more popular alternative, as the Conservative Party in the UK did with successive prime ministers David Cameron, Theresa May, Boris Johnson, Liz Truss, and Rishi Sunak.

Although Bagehot praised parliamentary governments for allowing an election to take place at any time, the lack of a definite election calendar can be abused. Under some systems, such as the British, a ruling party can schedule elections when it believes that it is likely to retain power, and so avoid elections at times of unpopularity. (From 2011, election timing in the UK was partially fixed under the Fixed-term Parliaments Act 2011, which was repealed by the Dissolution and Calling of Parliament Act 2022.) Thus, by a shrewd timing of elections, in a parliamentary system, a party can extend its rule for longer than is feasible in a presidential system. This problem can be alleviated somewhat by setting fixed dates for parliamentary elections, as is the case in several of Australia's state parliaments. In other systems, such as the Dutch and the Belgian, the ruling party or coalition has some flexibility in determining the election date. Conversely, flexibility in the timing of parliamentary elections can avoid periods of legislative gridlock that can occur in a fixed period presidential system. In any case, voters ultimately have the power to choose whether to vote for the ruling party or someone else.

Disadvantages

Incomplete separation of power

This section may lend undue weight to this section by making broad generalisations based solely on one citation, and looking solely at one country's parliamentary system. Please help improve it by rewriting it in a balanced fashion that contextualizes different points of view. (January 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

According to Arturo Fontaine, parliamentary systems in Europe have yielded very powerful heads of government which is rather what is often criticized about presidential systems. Fontaine compares United Kingdom's Margaret Thatcher to the United States' Ronald Reagan noting the former head of government was much more powerful despite governing under a parliamentary system. The rise to power of Viktor Orbán in Hungary has been claimed to show how parliamentary systems can be subverted. The situation in Hungary was according to Fontaine allowed by the deficient separation of powers that characterises parliamentary and semi-presidential systems. Once Orbán's party got two-thirds of the seats in Parliament in a single election, a supermajority large enough to amend the Hungarian constitution, there was no institution that was able to balance the concentration of power. In a presidential system it would require at least two separate elections to create the same effect; the presidential election, and the legislative election, and that the president's party has the legislative supermajority required for constitutional amendments. Safeguards against this situation implementable in both systems include the establishment of an upper house or a requirement for external ratification of constitutional amendments such as a referendum. Fontaine also notes as a warning example of the flaws of parliamentary systems that if the United States had a parliamentary system, Donald Trump, as head of government, could have dissolved the United States Congress.

Legislative flip-flopping

This section may lend undue weight to by making broad generalisations but citing only one authority. Please help improve it by rewriting it in a balanced fashion that contextualizes different points of view. (January 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

The ability for strong parliamentary governments to push legislation through with the ease of fused power systems such as in the United Kingdom, whilst positive in allowing rapid adaptation when necessary e.g. the nationalisation of services during the world wars, in the opinion of some commentators does have its drawbacks. For instance, the flip-flopping of legislation back and forth as the majority in parliament changed between the Conservatives and Labour over the period 1940–1980, contesting over the nationalisation and privatisation of the British Steel Industry resulted in major instability for the British steel sector.

Political fragmentation

This section may lend undue weight to by making broad generalisations but citing only one authority. Please help improve it by rewriting it in a balanced fashion that contextualizes different points of view. (January 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

In R. Kent Weaver's book Are Parliamentary Systems Better?, he writes that an advantage of presidential systems is their ability to allow and accommodate more diverse viewpoints. He states that because "legislators are not compelled to vote against their constituents on matters of local concern, parties can serve as organizational and roll-call cuing vehicles without forcing out dissidents."

Democratic unaccountability

This section is written like a personal reflection, personal essay, or argumentative essay that states a Misplaced Pages editor's personal feelings or presents an original argument about a topic. Please help improve it by rewriting it in an encyclopedic style. (January 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
This section possibly contains original research. Nothing in the citation supports the statements in this section. Please improve it by verifying the claims made and adding inline citations. Statements consisting only of original research should be removed. (January 2024) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

All current parliamentary democracies see the indirect election or appointment of their head of government. As a result, the electorate has limited power to remove or install the person or party wielding the most power. Although strategic voting may enable the party of the prime minister to be removed or empowered, this can be at the expense of voters first preferences in the many parliamentary systems utilising first past the post, or having no effect in dislodging those parties who consistently form part of a coalition government, as with the current Dutch prime minister Mark Rutte and his party the VVD's 4 terms in office, despite their peak support reaching only 26.6% in 2012.

Countries

Main article: List of countries by system of government § Parliamentary systems

Africa

Country Connection between the legislature and the executive
 Botswana Parliament of Botswana elects the President who appoints the Cabinet
 Ethiopia Federal Parliamentary Assembly appoints the Council of Ministers
 Lesotho National Assembly of Lesotho determines the Prime Minister of Lesotho
 Mauritius National Assembly appoints the Cabinet of Mauritius
 Somalia Federal Parliament of Somalia elects the President who appoints the Prime Minister
 South Africa Parliament of South Africa elects the President who appoints the Cabinet
 Togo

National Assembly elects the President who appoints the Prime Minister

Americas

House of Representatives of Belize
Parliament of Canada
Country Connection between the legislature and the executive
 Antigua and Barbuda Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Representatives of Antigua and Barbuda is appointed Prime Minister of Antigua and Barbuda by the Governor-General of Antigua and Barbuda, who then appoints the Cabinet of Antigua and Barbuda on the advice of the Prime Minister
 The Bahamas Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Assembly of the Bahamas is appointed Prime Minister of the Bahamas by the Governor-General of the Bahamas, who then appoints the Cabinet of the Bahamas on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Barbados Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Assembly of Barbados is appointed Prime Minister of Barbados by the President of Barbados, who then appoints the Cabinet of Barbados on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Belize Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Representatives of Belize is appointed Prime Minister of Belize by the Governor-General of Belize, who then appoints the Cabinet of Belize on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Canada Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Commons of Canada is appointed Prime Minister of Canada by the Governor General of Canada, who then appoints the Cabinet of Canada on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Dominica Parliament approves the Cabinet of Dominica
 Grenada Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Representatives of Grenada is appointed Prime Minister of Grenada by the Governor-General of Grenada, who then appoints the Cabinet of Grenada on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Jamaica Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Representatives of Jamaica is appointed Prime Minister of Jamaica by the Governor-General of Jamaica, who then appoints the Cabinet of Jamaica on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Saint Kitts and Nevis Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the National Assembly of Saint Kitts and Nevis is appointed Prime Minister of Saint Kitts and Nevis by the Governor-General of Saint Kitts and Nevis, who then appoints the Cabinet of Saint Kitts and Nevis on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Saint Lucia Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Assembly of Saint Lucia is appointed Prime Minister of Saint Lucia by the Governor-General of Saint Lucia, who then appoints the Cabinet of Saint Lucia on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Saint Vincent and the Grenadines Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Assembly of Saint Vincent and the Grenadines is appointed Prime Minister of Saint Vincent and the Grenadines by the Governor-General of Saint Vincent and the Grenadines, who then appoints the Cabinet of Saint Vincent and the Grenadines on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Suriname National Assembly elects the President, who appoints the Cabinet of Suriname
 Trinidad and Tobago Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the House of Representatives of Trinidad and Tobago is appointed Prime Minister of Trinidad and Tobago by the President of Trinidad and Tobago, who then appoints the Cabinet of Trinidad and Tobago on the advice of the Prime Minister

Asia

National Assembly of Armenia
Jatiya Sangsad Bhaban, parliament building of Bangladesh
Sansad Bhavan, parliament building of India
Council of Representatives of Iraq
Knesset of Israel in Jerusalem
Parliament of Malaysia
Country Connection between the legislature and the executive
 Armenia National Assembly appoints and (no sooner than one year) can dismiss through the constructive vote of no confidence the Government of Armenia
 Bangladesh Jatiya Sangsad approves the Cabinet of Bangladesh
 Bhutan Parliament of Bhutan approves the Lhengye Zhungtshog
 Cambodia Parliament of Cambodia approves the Council of Ministers
 Republic of China (Taiwan)
  • 1947 Constitution: The Legislative Yuan approves the Executive Yuan in which the premier is nominated and appointed by the president, with the consent of the Legislative Yuan.
  • 2005 Amendments: The Legislative Yuan approves the Executive Yuan in which the premier is appointed by the president. The Legislative Yuan may vote for motion of no confidence.
 Georgia The Prime Minister is nominated by a political party that has secured the best results in the parliamentary election. The nominee must be approved by the Parliament and then formally appointed by the President. The Prime Minister then appoints the Cabinet of Ministers.
 India President of India appoints the leader of the political party or alliance that has the support of a majority in the Lok Sabha as Prime Minister of India, who then forms the Union Council of Ministers
 Iraq Council of Representatives approves the Cabinet of Iraq
 Israel A member of the Knesset that has the best chance of forming a coalition is given a mandate to do so by the President of Israel. On success, they are appointed as the Prime Minister of Israel. The Prime Minister then appoints the Cabinet of Israel.
 Japan National Diet nominates the Prime Minister who appoints the Cabinet of Japan
 Kuwait National Assembly approves the Crown Prince who appoints the Prime Minister who appoints the Cabinet of Kuwait
 Laos National Assembly elects the President who nominates the Prime Minister
 Lebanon Maronite Christian president is elected by the Parliament of Lebanon. He appoints the Prime Minister (a Sunni Muslim) and the cabinet. The Parliament thereafter approves the Cabinet of Lebanon through a vote of confidence (a simple majority).
 Malaysia Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the Dewan Rakyat is appointed Prime Minister of Malaysia by the Yang di-Pertuan Agong, who then appoints the Cabinet of Malaysia on the advice of the Prime Minister.
 Myanmar Assembly of the Union, by an electoral college, elects the President who forms the Cabinet of Myanmar. However, Myanmar is currently under the rule of the State Administration Council, which assumed power by coup d'état
   Nepal Parliament of Nepal elects the Prime Minister who, by turn, appoints the Cabinet of Nepal
 Pakistan Parliament of Pakistan elects the Prime Minister of Pakistan who has majority support of members of National Assembly of Pakistan. Cabinet of Pakistan is appointed by President of Pakistan on advice of Prime Minister.
 Singapore Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the Parliament of Singapore is appointed Prime Minister of Singapore by the President of Singapore, who then appoints the Cabinet of Singapore on the advice of the Prime Minister.
 Thailand The Monarch appoints the MP or individual nominated by in the House of Representatives (usually the leader of the largest party or coalition) as Prime Minister, who forms the Cabinet of Thailand.
 Vietnam National Assembly elects the President and Prime Minister who forms the Cabinet.

Europe

The administrative building of the Albanian Parliament
The Congress of Deputies, the lower chamber of Spanish Parliament
Country Connection between the legislature and the executive
 Albania The President of Albania nominates the candidate chosen by the party or coalition which holds a majority in the Parliament of Albania. The Parliament then approves the Cabinet. If the nomination is rejected by the Parliament, another candidate is chosen by the President within 10 days.
 Andorra
 Austria
 Belgium Federal Parliament approves the Cabinet of Belgium
 Bulgaria National Assembly appoints the Council of Ministers of Bulgaria
 Croatia Croatian Parliament approves President of Government and the Cabinet nominated by him/her.
 Czech Republic President of the Czech Republic appoints usually the leader of the largest party or coalition in the Chamber of Deputies of the Parliament as Prime Minister, who forms the Cabinet. The Prime Minister must gain a vote of confidence by the Chamber of Deputies.
 Denmark The Monarch appoints, based on recommendations from the leaders of the parties in Folketinget, the cabinet leader who is most likely to successfully assemble a Cabinet which will not be disapproved by a majority in Folketinget.
 Estonia Riigikogu elects the Prime Minister candidate nominated by the President of the Republic (normally this candidate is the leader of the parliamentary coalition of parties). The Government of the Republic of Estonia is later appointed by the President of the Republic under proposal of the approved Prime Minister candidate. The Riigikogu may remove the Prime Minister and any other member of the government through a motion of no confidence.
 Finland Parliament of Finland appoints the Cabinet of Finland
 Germany Bundestag elects the Federal Chancellor (after nomination from the President of Germany), who forms the Cabinet
 Greece Hellenic Parliament approves the Cabinet of Greece
 Hungary National Assembly approves the Cabinet of Hungary
 Iceland The President of Iceland appoints and discharges the Cabinet of Iceland. Ministers can not even resign without being discharged by presidential decree.
 Ireland Dáil Éireann nominates the Taoiseach, who is then appointed by the President of Ireland
 Italy Italian Parliament grants and revokes its confidence in the Cabinet of Italy, appointed by the President of Italy
 Kosovo Assembly of Kosovo appoints the Government of Kosovo
 Latvia Saeima appoints the Cabinet of Ministers of the Republic of Latvia
 Luxembourg Chamber of Deputies appoints the Cabinet of Luxembourg
 Malta House of Representatives appoints the Cabinet of Malta
 Moldova Parliament of Moldova appoints the Cabinet of Moldova
 Montenegro Parliament of Montenegro appoints the Government of Montenegro
 Netherlands Second Chamber of the States-General can dismiss the Cabinet of the Netherlands through a motion of no confidence
 North Macedonia Assembly approves the Government of North Macedonia
 Norway The Monarch appoints the MP leading the largest party or coalition in Stortinget as Prime Minister, who forms the Cabinet
 Poland
 Portugal After the elections for the Assembly of the Republic or the resignation of the previous government, the president listens to the parties in the Assembly of the Republic and invites someone to form a government, usually the leader of the biggest party. Then the president swears in the prime minister and the Government.
 San Marino
 Serbia National Assembly appoints the Government of Serbia
 Slovakia National Council approves the Government of Slovakia
 Slovenia National Assembly appoints the Government of Slovenia
 Spain The Congress of Deputies elects the President of the Government, who forms the Cabinet
 Sweden The Riksdag elects the Prime Minister, who in turn appoints the other members of the Government
 United Kingdom The Leader, almost invariably a Member of Parliament (MP) and of the political party which commands or is likely to command the confidence of a majority of the House of Commons, is appointed Prime Minister by the British sovereign, who then appoints members of the Cabinet on the nomination and advice of the Prime Minister.

Oceania

Parliament of Australia
Parliament of Vanuatu
Country Connection between the legislature and the executive
 Australia Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the Australian House of Representatives is appointed Prime Minister of Australia by the Governor-General of Australia, who then appoints the Cabinet of Australia on the advice of the Prime Minister
 New Zealand Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the New Zealand House of Representatives is appointed Prime Minister of New Zealand by the Governor-General of New Zealand, who then appoints the Cabinet of New Zealand on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Papua New Guinea Leader of the political party that has the support of a majority in the National Parliament is appointed Prime Minister of Papua New Guinea by the Governor-General of Papua New Guinea, who then appoints the Cabinet of Papua New Guinea on the advice of the Prime Minister
 Samoa Legislative Assembly appoints the Cabinet of Samoa
 Vanuatu Parliament of Vanuatu appoints the Cabinet of Vanuatu

See also

References

  1. "The Decreta of León of 1188 – The oldest documentary manifestation of the European parliamentary system". UNESCO Memory of the World. 2013. Archived from the original on 24 June 2016. Retrieved 21 May 2016.
  2. John Keane: The Life and Death of Democracy, London 2009, 169–176.
  3. Sánchez, Isabel (2004). La Diputació del General de Catalunya (1413-1479). Barcelona: Institut d'Estudis Catalans. p. 92. ISBN 9788472837508.
  4. Jobson, Adrian (2012). The First English Revolution: Simon de Montfort, Henry III and the Barons' War. Bloomsbury. pp. 173–4. ISBN 978-1-84725-226-5. Archived from the original on 1 August 2020. Retrieved 6 June 2020.
  5. "Simon de Montfort: The turning point for democracy that gets overlooked". BBC. 19 January 2015. Archived from the original on 19 January 2015. Retrieved 19 January 2015
  6. "The January Parliament and how it defined Britain". The Telegraph. 20 January 2015. Archived from the original on 23 January 2015. Retrieved 28 January 2015.
  7. Norgate, Kate (1894). "Montfort, Simon of (1208?-1265)" . In Lee, Sidney (ed.). Dictionary of National Biography. Vol. 38. London: Smith, Elder & Co.
  8. Kopstein, Jeffrey; Lichbach, Mark; Hanson, Stephen E., eds. (2014). Comparative Politics: Interests, Identities, and Institutions in a Changing Global Order (4, revised ed.). Cambridge University Press. pp. 37–9. ISBN 978-1139991384. Archived from the original on 30 June 2020. Retrieved 6 June 2020. Britain pioneered the system of liberal democracy that has now spread in one form or another to most of the world's countries
  9. "Constitutionalism: America & Beyond". Bureau of International Information Programs (IIP), U.S. Department of State. Archived from the original on 24 October 2014. Retrieved 30 October 2014. The earliest, and perhaps greatest, victory for liberalism was achieved in England. The rising commercial class that had supported the Tudor monarchy in the 16th century led the revolutionary battle in the 17th, and succeeded in establishing the supremacy of Parliament and, eventually, of the House of Commons. What emerged as the distinctive feature of modern constitutionalism was not the insistence on the idea that the king is subject to law (although this concept is an essential attribute of all constitutionalism). This notion was already well established in the Middle Ages. What was distinctive was the establishment of effective means of political control whereby the rule of law might be enforced. Modern constitutionalism was born with the political requirement that representative government depended upon the consent of citizen subjects.... However, as can be seen through provisions in the 1689 Bill of Rights, the English Revolution was fought not just to protect the rights of property (in the narrow sense) but to establish those liberties which liberals believed essential to human dignity and moral worth. The "rights of man" enumerated in the English Bill of Rights gradually were proclaimed beyond the boundaries of England, notably in the American Declaration of Independence of 1776 and in the French Declaration of the Rights of Man in 1789.
  10. Blick, Andrew; Jones, George (1 January 2012). "The Institution of Prime Minister". History of Government Blog. Government of the United Kingdom. Archived from the original on 10 March 2016.
  11. Carter, Byrum E. (2015) . "The Historical Development of the Office of Prime Minister". Office of the Prime Minister. Princeton University Press. ISBN 9781400878260. Archived from the original on 19 August 2020. Retrieved 6 June 2020.
  12. "How the Westminster Parliamentary System was exported around the World". University of Cambridge. 2 December 2013. Retrieved 16 December 2013.
  13. Seidle, F. Leslie; Docherty, David C. (2003). Reforming parliamentary democracy. McGill-Queen's University Press. p. 3. ISBN 9780773525085.
  14. Julian Go (2007). "A Globalizing Constitutionalism?, Views from the Postcolony, 1945–2000". In Arjomand, Saïd Amir (ed.). Constitutionalism and political reconstruction. Brill. pp. 92–94. ISBN 978-9004151741.
  15. Johnston, Douglas M.; Reisman, W. Michael (2008). The Historical Foundations of World Order. Leiden: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers. p. 571. ISBN 978-9047423935.
  16. Fieldhouse, David; Madden, Frederick (1990). Settler Self-Government, 1840–1900: The Development of Representative and Responsible Government (1. publ. ed.). New York: Greenwood Press. p. xxi. ISBN 978-0-313-27326-1.
  17. Patapan, Haig; Wanna, John; Weller, Patrick Moray (2005). Westminster Legacies: Democracy and Responsible Government in Asia and the Pacific. UNSW Press. ISBN 978-0-86840-848-4.
  18. Lijphart, Arend (1999). Patterns of democracy. New Haven: Yale University Press.
  19. Julian Go (2007). "A Globalizing Constitutionalism?, Views from the Postcolony, 1945–2000". In Arjomand, Saïd Amir (ed.). Constitutionalism and political reconstruction. Brill. pp. 92–94. ISBN 978-9004151741. Archived from the original on 1 August 2020. Retrieved 6 June 2020.
  20. "How the Westminster Parliamentary System was exported around the World". University of Cambridge. 2 December 2013. Archived from the original on 16 December 2013. Retrieved 16 December 2013.
  21. Seidle, F. Leslie; Docherty, David C. (2003). Reforming parliamentary democracy. McGill-Queen's University Press. p. 3. ISBN 9780773525085. Archived from the original on 19 August 2020. Retrieved 6 June 2020.
  22. "The Constitution of the People's Republic of Bangladesh". bdlaws.minlaw.gov.bd. Article 56. Retrieved 8 February 2023.
  23. "Sådan dannes en regering / Folketinget". 29 November 2016. Retrieved 31 July 2024.
  24. "The Assembleia da República as a body that exercises sovereign power / Folketinget". Retrieved 16 September 2024.
  25. Duverger, Maurice (September 1996). "Les monarchies républicaines" [The crowned republics] (PDF). Pouvoirs, revue française d'études constitutionnelles et politiques (in French). No. 78. Paris: Éditions du Seuil. pp. 107–120. ISBN 2-02-030123-7. ISSN 0152-0768. Archived from the original (PDF) on 1 October 2018. Retrieved 10 September 2016.
  26. Frosini, Justin Orlando (2008). Ferrari, Giuseppe Franco (ed.). Forms of State and Forms of Government. Giuffrè Editore. pp. 54–55. ISBN 9788814143885. Archived from the original on 19 August 2020. Retrieved 13 November 2016 – via Google Books.
  27. "The Anti-Defection Law – Intent and Impact Background Note for the Conference on Effective Legislatures" (PDF). Archived (PDF) from the original on 19 August 2019. Retrieved 16 December 2019.
  28. "Anti-defection law the challenges". legalservicesindia.com. Archived from the original on 2 December 2019. Retrieved 16 December 2019.
  29. "ANTI-DEFECTION LAW: A DEATH KNELL FOR PARLIAMENTARY DISSENT?" (PDF). NUJS Law Review. March 2012. Archived from the original (PDF) on 28 May 2016. Retrieved 15 May 2016.
  30. "[Columns] Anti-Defection Laws in India: Its flaws and its falls". 1 August 2019.
  31. "UK Parliament glossary". UK Parliament. 27 October 2022. Archived from the original on 28 September 2022. Retrieved 27 October 2022.
  32. "Our system of government". New Zealand Parliament. 20 January 2016. Archived from the original on 17 October 2022. Retrieved 27 October 2022.
  33. "Fixed-term Parliament Act 2011". UK Parliament. 26 November 2021. Archived from the original on 21 October 2022. Retrieved 27 October 2022.
  34. Fish, M. Steven; Kroenig, Matthew (2009). The Handbook of National Legislatures: A Global Survey. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511575655. ISBN 978-0-521-51466-8.
  35. ^ Weaver, R. Kent (1985). "Are Parliamentary Systems Better?". The Brookings Review. 3 (4): 16–25. doi:10.2307/20079894. ISSN 0745-1253. JSTOR 20079894.
  36. Norris, Pippa (1995). "The Politics of Electoral Reform in Britain". International Political Science Review. 16 (1): 65–78. doi:10.1177/019251219501600105. ISSN 0192-5121. JSTOR 1601169. S2CID 144867316.
  37. Sundquist, James L. (1992). Constitutional reform and effective government. Internet Archive. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
  38. Lederman, Daniel (November 2001). Accountability and Corruption: Political Institutions Matter. Policy Research Working Papers. World Bank. p. 27. doi:10.1596/1813-9450-2708.
  39. ^ Valenzuela Manguini, Álvaro (5 November 2021). "Arturo Fontaine: "Si se estableciera el semipresidencialismo, a poco andar el pueblo sentiría que ha sido engañado"". Emol (in Spanish). Retrieved 7 November 2021.
  40. Henley, Jon (14 December 2021). "'Teflon' Mark Rutte set for fourth Dutch term after record-breaking talks". The Guardian. Retrieved 27 October 2022.

External links

Government
Politics and government
Overviews
Systems
Philosophies
Functions
Components
Governance
processes
Politics
Academic
History
International
Related
Categories
Common types of government ministers and ministries
Leadership
Titles
Defence /
foreign affairs /
public safety
Economics/
infrastructure
Environment /
natural resources
Social
Other
Lists
Public services
Concepts
Basic services
Public utility
Public works
Social services
See also
Categories: