Misplaced Pages

Deflation: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 15:17, 7 November 2006 editJBKramer (talk | contribs)1,567 edits rv blocked user evading block← Previous edit Latest revision as of 12:43, 20 December 2024 edit undoAnomieBOT (talk | contribs)Bots6,578,580 editsm Dating maintenance tags: {{Recentism}} 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Decrease in the general price level of goods and services}}
{{redirect|Deflation}}
{{other uses}}
'''Deflation''' is a decrease in the general ], over a period of time. Deflation is the opposite of ]. The term is also used to refer to a decrease in the size of the ]. During deflation the demand for liquidity goes up, in preference to goods or interest. During deflation the ] of ] increases.
{{distinguish|text=], a slowdown in the inflation rate}}
{{macroeconomics sidebar}}
In ], '''deflation''' is a decrease in the general ] of goods and services.<ref>Robert J. Barro and Vittorio Grilli (1994), ''European Macroeconomics'', chap. 8, p. 142. {{ISBN|0-333-57764-7}}</ref> Deflation occurs when the ] rate falls below 0% (a negative ]). Inflation reduces the value of ] over time, but deflation increases it. This allows more goods and services to be bought than before with the same amount of currency. Deflation is distinct from ], a slowdown in the inflation rate; i.e., when inflation declines to a lower rate but is still positive.<ref>{{Cite book| last1 = O'Sullivan | first1 = Arthur | author-link = Arthur O'Sullivan (economist) | first2 = Steven M. | last2 = Sheffrin | author-link2 = Steven M. Sheffrin | title = Economics: Principles in Action | url = https://archive.org/details/economicsprincip00osul | url-access = limited | publisher = Pearson Prentice Hall | year = 2003 | location = Upper Saddle River, New Jersey | page = | isbn = 0-13-063085-3}}</ref>


Economists generally believe that a sudden deflationary shock is a problem in a modern economy because it increases the ] of ], especially if the deflation is unexpected. Deflation may also aggravate recessions and lead to a '''deflationary spiral''' {{see below|]}}.<ref>{{cite news|last1=Harry Wallop|first1=Harry Wallop|title=Deflation: why it is dangerous|url=https://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/economics/3478630/Deflation-why-it-is-dangerous.html |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20220112/https://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/economics/3478630/Deflation-why-it-is-dangerous.html |archive-date=2022-01-12 |url-access=subscription |url-status=live|access-date=20 September 2016|work=The Daily Telegraph|date=18 November 2008}}{{cbignore}}</ref><ref name="EconomistDeflation">{{cite journal |title=The Economist explains: Why deflation is bad |url=https://www.economist.com/blogs/economist-explains/2015/01/economist-explains-4 |journal=Economist |publisher=Economist magazine |access-date=20 September 2016|date=7 Jan 2015}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|last1=Krugman|first1=Paul|title=Why is Deflation Bad?|url=https://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/08/02/why-is-deflation-bad/|work=The New York Times|date=2 August 2010|access-date=20 September 2016}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|last1=Walker|first1=Andrew|title=Is deflation such a bad thing?|url=https://www.bbc.com/news/business-28009477|access-date=20 September 2016|work=BBC|date=29 January 2016}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|last1=Thoma|first1=Mark|title=Explainer: Why is deflation so harmful?|url=http://www.cbsnews.com/news/explainer-why-is-deflation-so-harmful/|website=Moneywatch|date=8 April 2014 |publisher=CBS|access-date=20 September 2016}}</ref><ref>Hummel, Jeffrey Rogers. "Death and Taxes, Including Inflation: the Public versus Economists" (January 2007). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090325235925/http://www.econjournalwatch.org/pdf/HummelCommentJanuary2007.pdf|date=2009-03-25}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal|last1=Blanchard|first1=O.|last2=Dell'Ariccia|first2=G.|last3=Mauro|first3=P.|title=Rethinking macroeconomic policy.|journal=Journal of Money, Credit and Banking|date=18 August 2010|volume=42|issue=1|pages=199–215|doi=10.1111/j.1538-4616.2010.00334.x|citeseerx=10.1.1.153.7293|s2cid=14824203}}</ref>
==Definition==


Some economists argue that prolonged deflationary periods are related to the underlying technological progress in an economy, because as productivity increases (]), the cost of goods decreases.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Bordo|first1=Michael D.|last2=Filardo|first2=Andrew J.|date=2005-11-01|title=Deflation in a Historical Perspective|url=http://www.bis.org/publ/work186.pdf|language=en|location=Rochester, NY|doi=10.2139/ssrn.860404|ssrn=860404|s2cid=153344185}}</ref>
The 'general price level' comprises the price of ]s, consumption ] and ].


Deflation usually happens when supply is high (when excess ] occurs), when demand is low (when ] decreases), or when the money supply decreases (sometimes in response to a ] created from ] or a ]) or because of a ] from the economy.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.investopedia.com/ask/answers/111414/what-causes-negative-inflation-or-deflation.asp|title = What Causes Negative Inflation (Deflation)?}}</ref> It can also occur when there is ] ] and too little ].<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://thismatter.com/economics/market-models.htm|title = Market Models: Pure Competition, Monopolistic Competition, Oligopoly, and Pure Monopoly}}</ref>{{better source needed|date=July 2023|reason=This is just some guy's blog. It doesn’t make sense. Too much competition and too little market concentration mean firms in the industry do not have opportunity to earn above-normal profit. It will not lead to deflation of an economy.}}
In the recent years, economists have also started to advocate including asset prices such as stocks and housing and other production goods into the general price level. They then speak of inflation or deflation in asset prices. Indeed, policies designed to fight inflation in goods, services and wages, have seemed to spur stock and housing price inflation, or asset bubbles.


==Causes and corresponding types==
As with inflation, there are economists who regard deflation as a purely monetary effect, when the ] constricts the money supply, and there are those who believe that ''price'' deflation is also caused by real factors as for instances a fall in business confidence, which reduces the ], i.e. the speed with which ''money'' is circulating.
{{more citations needed section|date=November 2014}}
In the ] (investment and saving equilibrium{{snd}}liquidity preference and money supply equilibrium model),<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Hicks |first=J. R. |date=1937 |title=Mr. Keynes and the "Classics"; A Suggested Interpretation |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1907242 |journal=Econometrica |volume=5 |issue=2 |pages=147–159 |doi=10.2307/1907242|jstor=1907242 }}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal |last=Meade |first=J. E. |date=1937 |title=A Simplified Model of Mr. Keynes' System |url=https://academic.oup.com/restud/article-lookup/doi/10.2307/2967607 |journal=The Review of Economic Studies |volume=4 |issue=2 |pages=98–107 |doi=10.2307/2967607|jstor=2967607 }}</ref><ref name=":0">{{Cite book |last=Blanchard |first=Olivier |title=Macroeconomics |date=2021 |publisher=Pearson |isbn=978-0-13-489789-9 |edition=8th |location=London |publication-date=2021 |language=en}}</ref> deflation is caused by a shift in the supply and demand curve for goods and services.{{cn|date=April 2024}} This in turn can be caused by an increase in supply, a fall in demand, or both.


When prices are falling, consumers have an incentive to delay purchases and consumption until prices fall further, which in turn reduces overall economic activity. When purchases are delayed, productive capacity is idled and investment falls, leading to further reductions in ]. This is the deflationary spiral. The way to reverse this quickly would be to introduce an ]. The government could increase productive spending on things like infrastructure or the central bank could start expanding the ].<ref name=":0" />
During deflation, while consumers can buy more with the same amount of money, they also have less access to money (e.g., as wages, debt, or the return realized on sales of their products). Consumers and producers who are in debt, such as mortgagors, suffer because as their nominal income drops, while their payments remain constant. ] worry about deflation, because many of the tools of ] become ineffective as the ''real cost'' of money, the interest rate ''minus'' the inflation rate, begins to turn higher again once the inflation rate drops below zero. While nominal interest rates do not fall below zero there are ways by which central banks can create an effective rate of interest below zero for favored customers, macroeconomic theory holds that reductions of the central bank interest rate become less effective as the nominal interest rate drops below 1%. Deflation may set off a ], where businesses slow or stop investing, because the investment ] is perceived as higher than just letting the money appreciate due to deflation. The deflationary spiral is the opposite of an inflationary spiral.


Deflation is also related to ], where investors and buyers will start hoarding money because its value is now increasing over time.<ref name="Hussman2010">{{cite web | last1 = Hussman | first1 =John O. | title = Bernanke Leaps into a Liquidity Trap | year = 2010 | url = http://www.hussmanfunds.com/wmc/wmc101025.htm }}</ref> This can produce a ] or it may lead to shortages that entice investments yielding more jobs and commodity production. A central bank cannot, normally, charge negative interest for money, and even charging zero interest often produces less stimulative effect than slightly higher rates of interest. In a ], this is because charging zero interest also means having zero return on government securities, or even negative return on short maturities. In an open economy, it creates a ] trade and devalues the currency. A devalued currency produces higher prices for imports without necessarily stimulating exports to a like degree.
Deflation is generally regarded as a negative in modern currency environments, because a deflationary spiral may cause large falls in GDP and purchasing power, and may take a very long time to correct.


Deflation is the natural condition of economies when the supply of money is fixed, or does not grow as quickly as population and the economy. When this happens, the available amount of hard currency per person falls, in effect making money more scarce, and consequently, the ] of each unit of currency increases. Deflation also occurs when improvements in production ] lower the overall price of goods. ] in the marketplace often prompts those producers to apply at least some portion of these cost savings into reducing the asking price for their goods. When this happens, consumers pay less for those goods, and consequently, deflation has occurred, since purchasing power has increased.
However, a deflationary bias is the norm under specie or money economies, as population and production tend to increase faster than the stock of ], conversely, an inflationary bias is the norm under '']'' money economies. There are also episodes where there may be deflation in only a particular kind or type of goods, such as commodities during the ] of 1982-1998.


Rising ] and reduced transportation cost created structural deflation during the accelerated productivity era from 1870 to 1900, but there was mild inflation for about a decade before the ] in 1913.<ref name="Wells1890"/> There was inflation during ], but deflation returned again after the war and during the 1930s depression. Most nations abandoned the ] in the 1930s so that there is less reason to expect deflation, aside from the collapse of speculative asset classes, under a ] with low productivity growth.
Deflation should not be confused with ] which is a slowing in the rate of inflation, that is, where the general level of prices are ''still'' increasing, but slower than before.


]}}
==Effects of deflation==
{{legend|#EE220C |Deflation}}
In mainstream economic theory deflation is a general reduction in the level of prices, or of the prices of an entire kind of asset or commodity. Deflation should not be confused with temporarily falling prices; instead, it is a ''sustained fall'' in general prices. In the IS-LM model this is caused by a shift in the supply and demand curve for goods and interest, particularly a fall in the aggregate level of ]. That is, there is a fall in how much the whole economy is willing to buy, and the going price for goods. Since this idles capacity, investment also falls, leading to further reductions in aggregate demand. This is the ]. The solution to falling aggregate demand is ] either from the central bank, by expanding the money supply, or by the fiscal authority to increase demand, and borrow at rates which are below those available to private entities.
{{legend-line|#1DB100 solid 3px|] increases year/year}}
]]
In ], deflation may be caused by a combination of the supply and demand for goods and the supply and demand for money, specifically the supply of money going down and the supply of goods going up. Historic episodes of deflation have often been associated with the supply of goods going up (due to increased productivity) without an increase in the supply of money, or (as with the ] and possibly Japan in the early 1990s) the demand for goods going down combined with a decrease in the money supply. Studies of the Great Depression by ] have indicated that, in response to decreased demand, the Federal Reserve of the time decreased the money supply, hence contributing to deflation.


Causes include, on the demand side:
In monetarists theory, deflation is defined in terms of a rise in the demand for money, based on the quantity of money available. The ] is founded on the Fisher equation (also called the equation of exchange),
* Growth deflation
:''MV = PT'',
* Hoarding
where ''M'' is the money supply, ''V'' is the velocity of money, ''P'' is the average price level and ''T'' is the total number of transactions.


And on the supply side:
In more recent economic thinking, deflation is related to risk, where the risk adjusted return of assets drops to negative, investors and buyers will hoard currency rather than invest it, even in the most solid of securities. This can produce the theoretical condition, much debated as to its practical possibility, of a ]. A central bank cannot, normally, charge negative interest for money, and even charging zero interest often produces less stimulative effect than slightly higher rates of interest. In a closed economy, this is because charging zero interest also means having zero return on government securities, or even negative return on short maturities. In an open economy it creates a carry trade and devalues the currency producing higher prices for imports without necessarily stimulating exports to a like degree. The experience of Japan during its 1988-2004 depression is thought to illustrate both of these problems.
* Bank credit deflation
* Debt deflation
* Decision on the money supply side
* Credit deflation


=== Growth deflation===
In monetarist theory deflation is related to a sustained reduction in the velocity of money or number of transacitons. This is attributed to a dramatic contraction of the money supply, perhaps in response to a falling exchange rate, or to adhere to a gold standard or other external monetary base requirement.
Growth deflation is an enduring decrease in the real cost of goods and services as the result of technological progress, accompanied by competitive price cuts, resulting in an increase in aggregate demand.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Beckworth |first1=David |title=Aggregate Supply-Driven Deflation and Its Implications for Macroeconomic Stability |journal=Cato Journal |volume=28 |issue=3 |publisher=Cato Institute |url=http://www.cato.org/pubs/journal/cj28n3/cj28n3-1.pdf |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20111009235909/http://www.cato.org/pubs/journal/cj28n3/cj28n3-1.pdf |archive-date=2011-10-09 }}</ref>


A structural deflation existed from the 1870s until the cycle upswing that started in 1895. The deflation was caused by the decrease in the production and distribution costs of goods. It resulted in competitive price cuts when markets were oversupplied. The mild inflation after 1895 was attributed to the increase in gold supply that had been occurring for decades.<ref>{{cite book|title=The Cost of Living in America: A Political History of Economic Statistics, 1880-2000 |last=Stapleford |first= Thomas|year= 2009|publisher =Cambridge University Peess|pages=69–73}}
Deflation is generally regarded negatively, as it is a tax on borrowers and on holders of illiquid assets, which accrues to the benefit of savers and of holders of liquid assets and currency. In this sense it is the opposite of inflation (or in the extreme, ]), which is a tax on currency holders and lenders in favor of borrowers and short term consumption. In modern economies, deflation is caused by a collapse in demand, and is associated with recession and long term economic depressions.
</ref> There was a sharp rise in prices during World War I, but deflation returned at the war's end. By contrast, under a fiat monetary system, there was high productivity growth from the end of ] until the 1960s, but no deflation.<ref>{{Cite journal | last1 = Kendrick | first1 = John | title = U.S. Productivity Performance in Perspective, Business Economics, October 1, 1991 | year =1991 | url = http://www.allbusiness.com/finance/262030-1.html }}</ref>


Historically not all episodes of deflation correspond with periods of poor economic growth.<ref>Andrew Atkeson and Patrick J. Kehoe of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160506171400/https://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/sr/sr331.pdf |date=2016-05-06 }}</ref>
In modern economies, as loan terms have grown in length and financing is integral to building and general business, the penalties associated with deflation have grown larger. Since deflation discourages investment and spending, because there is no reason to risk on future profits when the expectation of profits may be negative and the expectation of future prices is lower, it generally leads to, or is associated with a collapse in ]. Without the "hidden risk of inflation", it may become more prudent just to hold onto money, and not to spend or invest it.


Productivity and deflation are discussed in a 1940 study by the ] that gives productivity by major US industries from 1919 to 1939, along with real and nominal wages. Persistent deflation was clearly understood as being the result of the enormous gains in productivity of the period.<ref>{{Cite book| last1 = Bell| first1 = Spurgeon| title = Productivity, Wages and National Income, The Institute of Economics of the Brookings Institution| year = 1940|publisher=Waverly press}}</ref> By the late 1920s, most goods were over supplied, which contributed to high unemployment during the Great Depression.<ref name="Beaudreau1996">{{Cite book|title=Mass Production, the Stock Market Crash and the Great Depression |last=Beaudreau |first=Bernard C. |year=1996 |publisher=Authors Choice Press|location=New York, Lincoln, Shanghi }}</ref>
Deflation is, however, the natural condition of hard currency economies when the rate of increase in the supply of money is not maintained at a rate commensurate to positive population and general economic growth. When this happens, the available amount of hard currency per person falls, in effect making money scarcer; and consequently, the purchasing power of each unit of currency increases. The late 19th century provides an example of sustained deflation combined with economic development under these conditions.


=== Bank credit deflation===
Deflation also occurs when improvements in production efficiency lowers the overall price of goods. Improvements in production efficiency generally happen because economic producers of goods and services are motivated by a promise of increased profit margins, resulting from the production improvements that they make. But despite their profit motive, competition in the marketplace often prompts those producers to apply at least some portion of these cost savings into reducing the asking price for their goods. When this happens, consumers pay less for those goods; and consequently a deflationary pressure is introduced, since purchasing power has increased. Periods of rapid technological inovation can also produce deflationary pressures in goods or services that are becoming obsolete, as inventories are sold off. For example, when ink jet printers became readily available, dot matrix printers were sold off at much lower prices. However these deflationary pressures only become general if the technological improvements are across the economy, otherwise the economy will ] with demand and investment moving other areas. In essence localized deflationary effects will ] capital and demand for other goods and forms of production.
Bank credit deflation is a decrease in the bank credit supply due to bank failures or increased perceived risk of defaults by private entities or a contraction of the money supply by the central bank.<ref>Carapella, Francesca (2015). "Banking panics and deflation in dynamic general equilibrium". Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2015-018. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. {{doi|10.17016/FEDS.2015.018}}.
</ref>


===Debt deflation===
However in macroeconomics, "one man's expenditure is another man's income." What this means is that while currency holders benefit from deflation, those whose wages and assets are deflating are made worse off. Thus, deflation can actually cause hardship when to those with majority the majority of their income in wages or the majority of their assets held in illiquid form, such as homes, land, and other forms of private property. It also amplifies the sting of debt, since after some period of significant deflation the payments made in the service of a debt represent a larger amount of purchasing power than they did when the debt was first incurred. This means that unexpected deflation is a risk to borrowers, since it will mean that the ] could increase during the term of the loan, just as unexpected inflation is a risk to lenders who may see a reduction in the real rate of interest during the course of the loan.
{{Main|Debt deflation}}
Debt deflation is a complicated phenomenon associated with the end of long-term credit cycles. It was proposed as a theory by ] (1933) to explain the deflation of the ].<ref>{{cite journal|url=https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/3596|title=The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions |journal=Fraser|location=St Louis, Missouri|publisher=Federal Reserve|date=October 1933 |last1=Fisher |first1=Irving }}</ref>


===Money supply-side deflation===
This lesson about protracted deflationary cycles and their attendant hardships has been felt several times in modern history. During the 19th century, the ] brought about a huge increase in production efficiency, that happened to coincide with a relatively flat money-supply. These two deflationary catalysts led, simultaneously, not only to tremendous capital development, but also to tremendous deprivation for millions of people who were ill-equipped to deal with the dark side of deflation. Business owners-- on average, better educated in economic theory than their unfortunate cohorts (or just better able to withstand the economic stresses)-- recognized the deflation cycle as it unfolded, and positioned themselves to leverage its beneficial aspects.
From a monetarist perspective, deflation is caused primarily by a reduction in the ] or the amount of ] per person.


A historical analysis of money velocity and ] shows an inverse correlation: for a given percentage decrease in the ] the result is a nearly equal percentage increase in money velocity.<ref name="Hussman2010"/> This is to be expected because monetary base ({{math|{{var|M}}{{sub|{{var|B}}}})}}, ] of base money ({{math|{{var|V}}{{sub|{{var|B}}}})}}, price level ({{mvar|P}}) and real output ({{mvar|Y}}) are related by definition: {{math|{{var|M}}{{sub|{{var|B}}}}{{mvar|V}}{{sub|{{var|B}}}} {{=}} {{var|P}}{{var|Y}}}}.<ref>{{cite book|title=Money Mischief: Episodes in Monetary History|last=Friedman|first=Milton|year=1994|publisher=Houghton Mifflin Harcourt|isbn=9780547542225 |pages=38}}</ref> However, the monetary base is a much narrower definition of money than ]. Additionally, the velocity of the monetary base is interest-rate sensitive, the highest velocity being at the highest interest rates.<ref name="Hussman2010"/>
Hard money advocates argue that if there were no "rigidities" in an economy, then deflation should be a welcome effect, as the lowering of prices would allow more of the economy's effort to be moved to other areas of activity, thus increasing the total output of the economy. However, while there have been periods of 'beneficial' deflation more often it has led to the more severe form with negative impact to large segments of the populace and economy. Examples of deflationary pressures seen as beneficial in recent times are the rapid improvements in ] which are seen as having increased ] without increasing demand for scarce resources.


In the early history of the United States, there was no national currency and an insufficient supply of coinage.<ref name=" David Ginsburg">{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=nFkJTM2Rzc0C&q=how+gold+coins+circulated+in+nineteenth+century+america+ginsberg&pg=PA25|title=Gold Coins of the New Orleans Mint: How Gold Coins Circulated in 19th Century America|first= David|last= Ginsburg|year=2006| pages=25–33|publisher=Zyrus Press |isbn=9780974237169}}</ref> Banknotes were the majority of the money in circulation. During financial crises, many banks failed and their notes became worthless. Also, banknotes were discounted relative to gold and silver, the discount depended on the financial strength of the bank.<ref name=" Taylor 1951"/>
Since deflationary periods favor those who ''hold'' currency over those who do not, they are often matched with periods of rising populist sentiment, as in the late 19th century, when populists in the United States wanted to move off hard money standards and back to a money standard based on the more inflationary (because more abundantly available) metal silver.


In recent years changes in the money supply have historically taken a long time to show up in the price level, with a rule of thumb lag of at least 18 months. More recently Alan Greenspan cited the time lag as taking between 12 and 13 quarters.<ref>Greenspan interview on CNBC, 3 December 2010</ref>{{full citation needed|date=November 2022}} Bonds, equities and commodities have been suggested as reservoirs for buffering changes in the money supply.<ref>{{cite book|title=You Can Profit from a Monetary Crisis|last=Browne|first=Harry|year=1981|publisher=Ishi Press International |isbn=4-87187-322-6 }}</ref>
Most economists agree that the effects of modest long-term inflation are less damaging than deflation (which, even at best, is very hard to control). Deflation raises ] which are both difficult and costly for management to lower. This frequently leads to layoffs and makes employers reluctant to hire new workers, increasing ]. However, in the last 5 years or so, ''real'' wages for the average worker has remained fixed or actually decreased, with little effect on unemployment.


==Causes of deflation== ===Credit deflation===
In modern credit-based economies, deflation may be caused by the central bank ''initiating'' higher interest rates (i.e., to "control" inflation), thereby possibly popping an asset ]. In a credit-based economy, a slow-down or fall in lending leads to less money in circulation, with a further sharp fall in money supply as confidence reduces and velocity weakens, with a consequent sharp fall-off in demand for employment or goods. The fall in demand causes a fall in prices as a supply ] develops. This becomes a deflationary spiral when prices fall below the costs of financing production, or repaying debt levels incurred at the prior price level. Businesses, unable to make enough profit no matter how low they set prices, are then liquidated. Banks get assets that have fallen dramatically in value since their mortgage loan was made, and if they sell those assets, they further glut supply, which only exacerbates the situation. To slow or halt the deflationary spiral, banks will often withhold collecting on non-performing loans (], and most recently America and Spain). This is often no more than a stop-gap measure, because they must then restrict credit, since they do not have money to lend, which further reduces demand, and so on.
From a monetary perspective deflation is caused by a reduction in the velocity of money and/or the amount of ] per person. In a hard money economy, with limited specie sources, deflation is the more natural state of the economy - people multiply and economies grow faster than hard money is created. Within the market mechanism, capitalism is generally an engine of deflation: as capital stocks improve, and there are more competitors, the supply of goods goes up, which means prices must fall until they balance demand. Capitalism also drives efficiency and innovation which has a downward pull on prices. These are referred to as "Smithian" and "Schumpterian" capital effects respectively.


====Historical examples of credit deflation====
A distinction then, is sometimes drawn between deflation in hard ] economies, such as those on the ] and economies which run on ]. In modern credit based economies, a deflationary spiral may be caused by the central bank initiating higher interest rates to reduce inflation or inflation risks, thereby possibly popping an asset ]. It is also associated with the collapse of a ] which has been run at higher level of production than its allocation of capital and labor can support. In a credit based economy, a fall in money supply leads to a ]. This reduces the level of demand, which, in turn contracts the money supply, and a consequent sharp fall-off in demand for goods. Demand falls, and with the falling of demand, there is a fall in prices as a supply ] develops. This in turn leads holders of inventories to sell their stocks at lower prices, often at a loss, further depressing prices.
In the early economic history of the United States, cycles of inflation and deflation correlated with capital flows between regions, with money being loaned from the financial center in the Northeast to the commodity producing regions of the (mid)-West and South. In a ] manner, prices of commodities rose when capital was flowing in, that is, when banks were willing to lend, and fell in the depression years of 1818 and 1839 when banks called in loans.<ref name="North1966">
{{cite book |title = The Economic Growth of the United States 1790–1860
|last = North
|first = Douglas C.
|year = 1966
|publisher = W. W. Norton & Company
|location = New York, London
|isbn = 978-0-393-00346-8
|url-access = registration
|url = https://archive.org/details/economicgrowthof00doug
}}
</ref> Also, there was no national paper currency at the time and there was a scarcity of coins. Most money circulated as banknotes, which typically sold at a discount according to distance from the issuing bank and the bank's perceived financial strength.


When banks failed their notes were redeemed for bank reserves, which often did not result in payment at ], and sometimes the notes became worthless. Notes of weak surviving banks traded at steep discounts.<ref name="David Ginsburg"/><ref name="Taylor 1951"/> During the Great Depression, people who owed money to a bank whose deposits had been frozen would sometimes buy bank books (deposits of other people at the bank) at a discount and use them to pay off their debt at par value.<ref>Benjamin Roth, ed. James Ledbetter and Daniel B. Roth, ''The Great Depression: A Diary''. Perseus Books, 2009, p. 36. "A market for buying bank 'passbooks' also cropped up in places like Youngstown. If you were desperate enough in 1931 for money to buy basic necessities, you could get 60 to 70 cents on the dollar for your passbooks' value. Local newspapers even printed the weekly rates for buying and selling these passbooks as they became a commodity; Roth pasted one such rate chart into his diary."</ref>
This becomes a deflationary spiral when prices fall below the costs of financing production. Businesses, unable to make enough profit no matter how low they set prices, are then liquidated. Banks get assets which have fallen dramatically in value since they loaned the funds, and if they sell those assets, they further glut supply, which only exacerbates the situation. To slow or halt the deflationary spiral, banks will often withhold collecting on non-performing loans, as in Japan, most recently. This is often no more than a stop-gap measure, because they must then restrict credit, since they do not have money to lend, which further reduces demand, and so on.


Deflation occurred periodically in the U.S. during the 19th century (the most important exception was during the Civil War). This deflation was at times caused by technological progress that created significant economic growth, but at other times it was triggered by ] – notably the ] which caused deflation through 1844, and the ] which triggered the ] that lasted until 1879.<ref name="Wells1890"/><ref name="Taylor 1951"/><ref name="North1966"/> These deflationary periods preceded the establishment of the U.S. ] and its active management of monetary matters. Episodes of deflation have been rare and brief since the Federal Reserve was created (a notable exception being the ]) while U.S. economic progress has been unprecedented.
In unstable currency economies, barter and other alternate currency arrangements are common, and therefore when legal tender becomes scarce, or unusually unreliable, commerce can still continue. Since in such economies the central government is often unable, even if it were willing, to adequately control the internal economy, there is no pressing need for individuals to acquire official currency except to pay for imported goods. In effect, barter acts as protective tariff in such economies, encouraging local consumption of local production. It also acts as a spur to mining and exploration, since one way to make money in such an economy is to dig it out of the ground.


A financial crisis in England in 1818 caused banks to call in loans and curtail new lending, draining specie out of the U.S.{{citation needed|date=February 2021}} The Bank of the United States also reduced its lending. Prices for cotton and tobacco fell. The price of agricultural commodities also was pressured by a return of normal harvests following 1816, the '']'', that caused large scale famine and high agricultural prices.<ref>{{Harvnb|Taylor|1951|pp=336}}</ref>
When the central bank has lowered nominal interest rates all the way to zero, it can no longer further stimulate demand by lowering interest rates - "deflation is when the central bank cannot give money away". This is the famous ]. When deflation takes hold, it requires "special arrangements" to "lend" money at a zero nominal rate of interest, which could still be a very high ''real'' rate of interest, due to the inflation rate in order to intentionally increase the money supply.


There were several causes of the deflation of the severe depression of 1839–1843, which included an oversupply of agricultural commodities (importantly cotton) as new cropland came into production following large federal land sales a few years earlier, banks requiring payment in gold or silver, the failure of several banks, default by several states on their bonds and British banks cutting back on specie flow to the U.S.<ref name="North1966"/><ref>{{cite web
This cycle has been traced out on the broad scale during the ]. Specifically when the collapse of the led to the subsequent collapse of the entire global financial system. International trade contracted sharply, severely reducing demand for goods, thereby idling a great deal of capacity, and setting off a string of bank failures. A similar situation in Japan, beginning with the stock and real estate market collapse in the early 1990s, was arrested by the Japanese government preventing the collapse of most banks and taking over direct control of several in the worst condition. These occurrences are the matter of intense debate. There are economists who argue that the post-2000 recession had a period where the US was at risk of severe deflation, and that therefore the ] central bank was right in holding interest rates at an "accommodative" stance from 2001 on.
| last1 = Wallis
| first1 = Hohn Joseph
| last2 = National Bureau of Economic Research
| title = The Depression of 1839 to 1843
| url = http://www.startabank.com/history/200809_TheDepression/depression1839.pdf
}}</ref>


This cycle has been traced out on a broad scale during the ]. Partly because of overcapacity and market saturation and partly as a result of the ], international trade contracted sharply, severely reducing demand for goods, thereby idling a great deal of capacity, and setting off a string of bank failures.<ref name="Beaudreau1996" /> A similar situation in Japan, beginning with the stock and real estate market collapse in the early 1990s, was arrested by the Japanese government preventing the collapse of most banks and taking over direct control of several in the worst condition.
] insist on the distinction between consuming goods and producing goods, and less often between exogeneous and endogeneous money supply.


===Scarcity of official money===
For a given money supply, if wages rise faster than productivity, profits will fall, and with them the price of productive goods, while consuming goods will rise. This happens in times when labor supply is tight and bargaining power is strong. When wages rise slower than productivity, profits rise as do the prices of assets relative to consuming goods. This can occur when labor supply is great and bargaining power is weak. In the first case there should, all other things being equal, be inflation, because there is higher consumption demand and less investment. In the second case, all other things being equal, there should be deflation, as there is a drop in consuming demand and a rise in investment. A deflationary spiral occurs when the drop in demand is sufficient to also reduce expected profits for long enough to reduce the value of capital as well. Thus less consumption and less investment feed off of each other.
The United States had no national paper money until 1862 (] used to fund the Civil War), but these notes were discounted to gold until 1877. There was also a shortage of U.S. minted coins. Foreign coins, such as Mexican silver, were commonly used.<ref name="David Ginsburg"/> At times banknotes were as much as 80% of currency in circulation before the Civil War. In the financial crises of 1818–19 and 1837–1841, many banks failed, leaving their money to be redeemed below ] from reserves. Sometimes the notes became worthless, and the notes of weak surviving banks were heavily discounted.<ref name="Taylor 1951"/> The Jackson administration opened branch mints, which over time increased the supply of coins. Following the 1848 finding of gold in the ], enough gold came to market to devalue gold relative to silver. To equalize the value of the two metals in coinage, the US mint slightly reduced the silver content of new coinage in 1853.<ref name="David Ginsburg"/>


When structural deflation appeared in the years following 1870, a common explanation given by various government inquiry committees was a scarcity of gold and silver, although they usually mentioned the changes in industry and trade we now call productivity. However, ] (1890) notes that the U.S. money supply during the period 1879-1889 actually rose 60%, the increase being in gold and silver, which rose against the percentage of national bank and legal tender notes. Furthermore, Wells argued that the deflation only lowered the cost of goods that benefited from recent improved methods of manufacturing and transportation. Goods produced by craftsmen did not decrease in price, nor did many services, and the cost of labor actually increased. Also, deflation did not occur in countries that did not have modern manufacturing, transportation and communications.<ref name="Wells1890">{{cite book
Since, in the Keynesian view, the source of deflation is a lack of consumer demand, and a lack of confidence to invest Keynesians advocate "pump priming" or government creation of credit/money that has a cost ] below inflation or market rates. As witnessed since 1990 in Japan, and in the 1930's in the USA, this policy is not very effective unless government creates employment via public works projects or military manufacturing.
|title=Recent Economic Changes and Their Effect on Production and Distribution of Wealth and Well-Being of Society
|last=Wells
|first=David A.
|year=1890 |publisher= D. Appleton and Co.|location= New York|isbn= 0-543-72474-3 |url= https://archive.org/details/recenteconomicc01wellgoog
|chapter=Money supply |page=222}}</ref>


By the end of the 19th century, deflation ended and turned to mild inflation. ] predicted rising gold supply would cause inflation decades before it actually did. ] blamed the worldwide inflation of the pre-WWI years on rising gold supply.<ref>
The reason this view has become the dominant one in deflation fighting is because the most important alternate view prior to Keynes was that increasing business confidence was the way to end business downturns, and the most important steps to doing this were to instill confidence in holders of currency that their buying power was secure. Classical political economy held that ] was true, and that economies would self-right themselves after a period of monetary adjustment, unless there was interference from some external, probably government, source. Hence, the previous policy regime prescribed balancing government budgets by lowering expenditures and raising taxes, and raising interest rates to give holders of currency more incentive to lend. The general view in mainstream economics is that this lead to the "Great Contraction" of money supply in the 1928-1932 period, which was a contributing, or even primary, cause of during a downturn in business into what is known as ].
{{cite book |title=The Cost of Living in America: A Political History of Economic Statistics, 1880–2000 |last=Stapleford |first= Thomas |year=2009|publisher=Cambridge University Press |pages=69–73}}
</ref>


In economies with an unstable currency, barter and other alternate currency arrangements such as ] are common, and therefore when the 'official' money becomes scarce (or unusually unreliable), commerce can still continue (e.g., most recently in ]). Since in such economies the central government is often unable, even if it were willing, to adequately control the internal economy, there is no pressing need for individuals to acquire official currency except to pay for imported goods.
In modern monetarist theory, monetary policy is thought to be a more effective means of ending deflationary spirals, by flooding an economy with liquidity. It was this policy which was pursued by the United States in the early 2000s in order to fight off what was seen as a potential deflationary spiral.


===Currency pegs and monetary unions===
With the rise of ] ideas, the focus in fighting deflation was put on expanding demand by lowering interest rates (i.e., reducing the "cost" of money). This view has received a setback in light of the failure of accommodative policies in both Japan and the US to spur demand after stock market shocks in the early 1990s and in 2000 - 2002, respectively. Economists now worry about the inflationary impact of monetary policies on asset prices. Sustained low real rates can be the direct cause of higher asset prices and excessive debt accumulation. Therefore lowering rates may prove only a temporarily palliative, leading to the aggravation of an eventual future debt deflation crisis. These arguments parallel some made during the 1880-1920 period about the possibility that over-investment could be a cause, or contributing cause, in economic downturns.
If a country ] its currency to one of another country that features a higher ] or a more favourable ] development, it must – to maintain its competitiveness – either become equally more productive or lower its ] (e.g., wages). Cutting factor prices fosters deflation. ]s have a similar effect to currency pegs.


==Effects==
{{More citations needed|section|date=September 2022}}


=== On spending and borrowing ===
<!-- &&&& -->
Some believe that, in the absence of large amounts of debt, deflation would be a welcome effect because the lowering of prices increases ].<ref>{{cite journal| last =Selgin| first =George| title =Less Than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy| journal =IEA Hobart Paper| volume =32| page =87| publisher =]| location =London| date =1997| url =http://www.iea.org.uk/sites/default/files/publications/files/upldbook98pdf.pdf| issn =0073-2818| access-date =4 December 2014 }}</ref> However, while an increase in the purchasing power of one's money benefits some, it amplifies the sting of debt for others: after a period of deflation, the payments to service a debt represent a larger amount of purchasing power than they did when the debt was first incurred. Consequently, deflation can be thought of as an effective increase in a loan's interest rate. If, as during the ] in the United States, deflation averages 10% per year, even an interest-free loan is unattractive as it must be repaid with money worth 10% more each year.


Under normal conditions, most central banks, such as the Federal Reserve, implement policy by setting a target for a short-term interest rate{{snd}} the overnight ] in the U.S.{{snd}} and enforcing that target by buying and selling securities in open capital markets. When the short-term interest rate hits zero, the central bank can no longer ease policy by lowering its usual interest-rate target. With interest rates near zero, ] becomes an increasingly important tool in managing deflation.
===Alternative causes and effects===
====The Austrian school of economics====
The ] defines deflation and inflation solely in relation to the money supply. Deflation is therefore defined to be a contraction of the money supply. Under this definition, the Austrian school sees deflation as a cause of a general fall in prices, not a general fall in prices itself. They attribute the other main cause of a general fall in prices to be an increase of productivity relative to the money supply.


In recent times, as loan terms have grown in length and loan financing (or leveraging) is common among many types of investments, the costs of deflation to borrowers has grown larger.
For instance if there is a fixed money supply of 400 kg of gold in an economy that produces 200 ], then one widget will cost 2 kg of gold. However, next year if output is 400 widgets with the same money supply of 400 kg of gold the price of each widget will drop to 1 kg of gold. In this case the general fall in price was caused by increased productivity.


=== On savings and investments ===
The opposite of the above scenario has the same effect on prices, but a different cause. If there is a fixed money supply of 400 kg of gold in an economy that produces 200 widgets, then once again each widget will cost 2 kg of gold. However, if next year the money supply is cut in half to 200 kg of gold with the same output of 200 widgets, the price of each widget will now only be 1 kg of gold. When capital profits are dropping rapidly, there is no reason to invest gold, which breaks the ], and thus the automatic tendency of the economy to move back to equilibrium.
Deflation can discourage private investment, because there is reduced expectations on future profits when future prices are lower. Consequently, with reduced private investments, ] can cause a collapse in ]. Without the "hidden risk of inflation", it may become more prudent for institutions to hold on to money, and not to spend or invest it (burying money). They are therefore rewarded by ] and holding money. This "hoarding" behavior is seen as undesirable by most economists.{{citation needed|reason=Hayek's word alone is not a reliable source regarding what most economists think, especially when he was writing in 1932. Other sources are needed, particularly reflecting the state of the field in the 21st century.|date=September 2022}} ], a ] ], wrote that:


{{Blockquote|It is agreed that hoarding money, whether in cash or in idle balances, is deflationary in its effects. No one thinks that deflation is in itself desirable.|source=Hayek (1932)<ref>{{cite web |url=http://butnowyouknow.net/those-who-fail-to-learn-from-history/hayeks-1932-letter-on-the-great-depression/ |title=Hayek's 1932 Letter on the Great Depression |work=But Now You Know|date=25 November 2010 }}</ref>}}
Austrians view increased productivity to be a good cause of a general fall in prices, while credit/money supply contraction as being a bad cause of a general fall in prices. Austrians contend that in the first scenario wages will remain the same because of the unchanged money supply but that a general increase in wealth will be reflected in lower prices. Austrians also take the position that there are no negative distortions in the economy due to a general fall in prices in the first scenario. However, in the second scenario where a general fall in prices is caused by deflation, Austrians contend that this confers no benefit to society. For in this scenario wages will simply be cut in half and lower prices will not reflect a general increase in wealth. In addition, Austrians believe that deflation causes negative distortions in the economy with debtors and creditors as well as other areas.


== Compared with inflation ==
==Examples of deflation==
Deflation causes a transfer of wealth from borrowers and holders of illiquid assets to the benefit of savers and of holders of liquid assets and currency, and because confused ]s cause ] in the form of underinvestment. In this sense, its effects are the opposite of inflation, the effect of which is to transfer wealth from currency holders and lenders (savers) and to borrowers, including governments, and cause overinvestment. Whereas inflation encourages short term consumption and can similarly overstimulate investment in projects that may not be worthwhile in real terms (for example, the ] and ]s), deflation reduces investment even when there is a real-world demand not being met. In modern economies, deflation is usually associated with economic depression, as occurred in the ] and the ]. Deflation was present during most economic depressions in US history.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://butnowyouknow.net/those-who-fail-to-learn-from-history/history-of-economic-downturns-in-the-us/|title=The History of Economic Downturns in the US|work=But Now You Know|date=6 December 2008}}</ref>{{better source needed|date=September 2022}}


==Deflationary spiral==
=== United Kingdom ===
During ] the ] ] was removed from the gold standard. The motivation for this policy change was to finance the ]; one of the results was inflation, and a rise in the gold price, along with the corresponding drop in international exchange rates for the pound. When the pound was returned to the gold standard after the war it was done on the basis of the pre-war gold price, which, since it was higher than equivalent price in gold, required prices to fall to realign with the higher target value of the pound.


A ''deflationary spiral'' is a situation where decreases in the price level lead to lower production, which in turn leads to lower wages and demand, which leads to further decreases in the price level.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/spiral.html|title=DEFLATIONARY SPIRALS}}</ref><ref name="academia.edu">Grinin, L. E., & Korotayev, A. V. (2018). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201112025952/https://www.academia.edu/36117858/The_Future_of_the_Global_Economy_in_the_Light_of_Inflationary_and_Deflationary_Trends_and_Long_Cycles_Theory |date=2020-11-12 }}.</ref> Since reductions in general price level are called deflation, a deflationary spiral occurs when reductions in price lead to a ], where a problem exacerbates its own cause.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Kagan |first1=Julia |title=Deflationary Spiral |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/d/deflationary-spiral.asp |website=Investopedia |access-date=20 March 2021 |language=en}}</ref> In science, this effect is also known as a ] loop. Another economic example of this situation in economics is the ].
===Deflation in the United States===
====Major deflations====
There have been two significant periods of deflation in the United States. The first was after the ].
<blockquote>"The Great Sag of 1873-96 could be near the top of the list. Its scope was global. It featured cost-cutting and productivity-enhancing technologies. It flummoxed the experts with its persistence, and it resisted attempts by politicians to understand it, let alone reverse it. It delivered a generation’s worth of rising bond prices, as well as the usual losses to unwary creditors via defaults and early calls. Between 1875 and 1896, according to Milton Friedman, prices fell in the United States by 1.7% a year, and in Britain by 0.8% a year.</blockquote>


The ] was regarded by some as a deflationary spiral.<ref>{{cite news|url=http://www.economist.com/economics-a-to-z/d#node-21529653|title=Economics A-Z terms beginning with D|newspaper=The Economist}}</ref> A deflationary spiral is the modern ] version of the ] controversy of the 19th century. Another related idea is ]'s theory that ].
The second was between 1930-1933 when the rate of deflation was approximately 10 percent/year. The first was possibly spurred by the deliberate policy in retiring paper money printed during the Civil War; the second was part of America's slide into the ], where ]s failed and ] peaked at 25%. Both were world-wide phenomena.


==Counteracting deflation==
The deflation of the Great Depression did not occur because of any sudden rise or surplus in output. It is generally thought that, because there was an enormous contraction of ] and the money supply into an environment of high asset prices, an ordinary downturn in business was turned into a catastrophic drop in production. The lack of liquidity generated ] created an environment where ] was in frantic demand, and the ] did not adequately accommodate that demand, so even sound banks toppled one-by-one (because they were unable to meet the sudden demand for cash— see ]). From the standpoint of the Fisher equation (see above), there was a concommitant drop both in money supply (credit) and the ] which was so profound that deflation took hold despite the increases in money supply spurred by the Federal Reserve.
During severe deflation, targeting an interest rate (the usual method of determining how much currency to create) may be ineffective, because even lowering the short-term interest rate to zero may result in a real interest rate which is too high to attract credit-worthy borrowers. In the 21st-century, negative interest rates have been tried, but it cannot be too negative, since people might withdraw cash from bank accounts if they have a negative interest rate. Thus the central bank must directly set a target for the quantity of money (called "]") and may use extraordinary methods to increase the supply of money, e.g. purchasing financial assets of a type not usually used by the central bank as reserves (such as ]). Before he was ] of the United States ], ] claimed in 2002, "sufficient injections of money will ultimately always reverse a deflation",<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081024060408/http://www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2002/20021121/default.htm |date=2008-10-24 }}. Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke before the National Economists Club, Washington, D.C., November 21, 2002. Federal Reserve.</ref> although Japan's deflationary spiral was not broken by the amount of quantitative easing provided by the Bank of Japan.


Until the 1930s, it was commonly believed by ] that deflation would cure itself. As prices decreased, demand would naturally increase, and the economic system would correct itself without outside intervention.
====Minor deflations====
Throughout the history of the United States, inflation has approached zero and dipped below for short periods of time (negative inflation is deflation). This was quite common in the 19th century and in the 20th century before ].


This view was challenged in the 1930s during the ]. ] argued that the economic system was not self-correcting with respect to deflation and that governments and central banks had to take active measures to boost demand through tax cuts or increases in government spending. Reserve requirements from the central bank were high compared to recent times. So were it not for redemption of currency for gold (in accordance with the gold standard), the central bank could have effectively increased money supply by simply reducing the reserve requirements and through ] (e.g., buying treasury bonds for cash) to offset the reduction of money supply in the private sectors due to the collapse of credit (credit is a form of money).
===Deflation in Hong Kong===
Following the ] in late ], ] experienced a long period of deflation which did not end until the 4th quarter of ] . Many ]n currencies devalued following the crisis. The ], however, was pegged to the ]. The gap was filled by deflation of ]. The situation is worsened with cheap commodity goods from ], and weak consumer confidence. According to ], Hong Kong was the economy with lowest inflation in ] .


With the rise of ] ideas, the focus in fighting deflation was put on expanding demand by lowering interest rates (i.e., reducing the "cost" of money). This view has received criticism in light of the failure of accommodative policies in both Japan and the US to spur demand after stock market shocks in the early 1990s and in 2000–2002, respectively. ] worry about the inflationary impact of monetary policies on asset prices. Sustained low real rates can cause higher asset prices and excessive debt accumulation. Therefore, lowering rates may prove to be only a temporary palliative, aggravating an eventual debt deflation crisis.
===Deflation in Japan===

Deflation started in the early ]s. The ] and the government have tried to eliminate it by reducing interest rates, but despite having them near zero for a long period of time, they have not succeeded. In July 2006, the zero-rate policy was ended.
===Special borrowing arrangements===
When the central bank has lowered nominal interest rates to zero, it can no longer further stimulate demand by lowering interest rates. This is the famous ]. When deflation takes hold, it requires "]" to lend money at a zero nominal rate of interest (which could still be a very high ''real'' rate of interest, due to the ''negative'' inflation rate) in order to artificially increase the money supply.

=== Capital ===

Although the values of ]s are often casually said to deflate when they decline, this usage is not consistent with the usual definition of deflation; a more accurate description for a decrease in the value of a capital asset is ]. Another term, the ] are standards to determine a decrease in values of capital assets when market values are not readily available or practical.

==Historical examples==

{{recentism|section=yes|reason=Examples are generally in reverse chronological order, while the case of the Spanish Empire among other highly notable ones isn’t even mentioned. Rather egregious|date=December 2024}}

=== EU countries ===
The inflation rate of ] was negative during three years from 2013 to 2015. The same applies to ], ], ], and ] from 2014 to 2016. Greece, Cyprus, Spain, and Slovakia are members of the ]. The Bulgarian currency, the ], is ] to the ] with a fixed exchange rate. In the entire ] and the ], a ]ary development was to be observed in the years 2011 to 2015.

{| class="wikitable" style="text-align:center"
|-
! Year !! Bulgaria !! Greece !! Cyprus !! Spain !! Slovakia !! EU !! Eurozone
|-
| 2011 || 3.4 || 3.1 || 3.5 || 3.0 || 4.1 || 3.1 || 2.7
|-
| 2012 || 2.4 || 1.0 || 3.1 || 2.4 || 3.7 || 2.6 || 2.5
|-
| 2013 || 0.4 || style="background: yellow;"| −0.9 || 0.4 || 1.5 || 1.5 || 1.5 || 1.4
|-
| 2014 || style="background: yellow;"| −1.6 || style="background: yellow;"| −1.4 || style="background: yellow;"| −0.3 || style="background: yellow;"| −0.2 || style="background: yellow;"| −0.1 || 0.6 || 0.4
|-
| 2015 || style="background: yellow;"| −1.1 || style="background: yellow;"| −1.1 || style="background: yellow;"| −1.5 || style="background: yellow;"| −0.6 || style="background: yellow;"| −0.3 || 0.1 || 0.2
|-
| 2016 || style="background: yellow;"| −1.3 || 0.0 || style="background: yellow;"| −1.2 ||style="background: yellow;"| −0.3 || style="background: yellow;"| −0.5 || 0.2 || 0.2
|-
| 2017 || 1.2 || 1.1 || 0.7 || 2.0 || 1.4 || 1.7 || 1.5
|}
Table: ]. Annual average rate of change (%) (HICP inflation rate).<ref>{{cite web |publisher=Eurostat|title=HICP - inflation rate |url=https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/tec00118/default/table?lang=en |access-date=8 February 2021}}</ref> Negative values are highlighted in colour.

===Hong Kong===
Following the ] in late 1997, ] experienced a long period of deflation which did not end until the fourth quarter of 2004.<ref> {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20050308003234/http://www.info.gov.hk/censtatd/eng/hkstat/fas/cpi/cpi_adjust_index.html|date=March 8, 2005}}</ref> Many ]n currencies devalued following the crisis. The ], however, was pegged to the ], leading to an adjustment instead by a deflation of ]. The situation was worsened by the increasingly cheap exports from ], and "weak ]" in Hong Kong. This deflation was accompanied by an economic slump that was more severe and prolonged than those of the surrounding countries that devalued their currencies in the wake of the Asian financial crisis.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Jao|first=Y. C.|title=The Asian Financial Crisis and the Ordeal of Hong Kong |url=https://archive.org/details/asianfinancialcr00jaoy|url-access=limited|publisher=Quorum Books |year=2001 |pages=–170 |chapter=Why Was Hong Kong a Laggard in Economic Recovery |isbn=978-1-56720-447-6 }}</ref><ref>{{Cite news|url=http://www.atimes.com/atimes/China/EG04Ad04.html |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20030708025924/http://www.atimes.com/atimes/China/EG04Ad04.html |url-status=unfit |archive-date=2003-07-08 |title=Why Hong Kong is in crisis|last=Liu |first=Henry C. K. |date=2003-07-04 |publisher=Asia Times |access-date=27 April 2010 }}</ref>

===Ireland===
In February 2009, ]'s ] announced that during January 2009, the country experienced deflation, with prices falling by 0.1% from the same time in 2008. This was the first time deflation has hit the Irish economy since 1960. Overall consumer prices decreased by 1.7% in the month.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.rte.ie/news/2009/0212/inflation.html|title=First annual negative inflation in 49 years|date=12 February 2009|work=RTE.ie}}</ref>

Brian Lenihan, Ireland's Minister for Finance, mentioned deflation in an interview with RTÉ Radio. According to RTÉ's account,<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180903150802/https://www.rte.ie/news/2009/1113/124186-budget2010/ |date=2018-09-03 }}, ''RTE News'', 9 December 2009</ref> "Minister for Finance Brian Lenihan has said that deflation must be taken into account when Budget cuts in child benefit, public sector pay and professional fees are being considered. Mr Lenihan said month-on-month there has been a 6.6% decline in the cost of living this year."

This interview is notable in that the deflation referred to is not discernibly regarded negatively by the Minister in the interview. The Minister mentions the deflation as an item of data helpful to the arguments for a cut in certain benefits. The alleged economic harm caused by deflation is not alluded to or mentioned by this member of government. This is a notable example of deflation in the modern era being discussed by a senior financial Minister without any mention of how it might be avoided, or whether it should be.<ref> {{webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100226052533/http://www.rte.ie/news/2009/1113/budget.html |date=February 26, 2010 }}</ref>{{original research inline|date=April 2013}}

===Japan===
{{More citations needed section|date=September 2010}}

Deflation started in the early 1990s.<ref name="academia.edu"/> The ] and the government tried to eliminate it by reducing interest rates and "]," but did not create a sustained increase in broad money and deflation persisted. In July 2006, the zero-rate policy was ended.


Systemic reasons for deflation in Japan can be said to include: Systemic reasons for deflation in Japan can be said to include:


* ]: The Bank of Japan kept monetary policy loose only when inflation was below zero, tightening whenever deflation ends.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.themoneyillusion.com/?p=7337 |title=Meet the new BOJ, same as the old BOJ |publisher=TheMoneyIllusion |date=2010-10-05 |access-date=2013-02-14}}</ref>
*Fallen ] prices. There was a rather large ] in both ] and ] in Japan in the 1980s (peaking in late ]). When assets decrease in value, the money supply shrinks, which is deflationary.
* ]: Japan has an aging population (22.6% over age 65) which has been declining since 2011, as the death rate exceeds the birth rate.<ref>{{Cite news|last=Dooley|first=Ben|date=2019-12-24|title=Japan Shrinks by 500,000 People as Births Fall to Lowest Number Since 1874 (Published 2019)|language=en-US|work=The New York Times|url=https://www.nytimes.com/2019/12/24/world/asia/japan-birthrate-shrink.html|access-date=2021-02-04|issn=0362-4331}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|date=2019-06-06|title=Statistics Bureau Home Page/Population Estimates Monthly Report|url=http://www.stat.go.jp/english/data/jinsui/tsuki/index.html|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190606203315/http://www.stat.go.jp/english/data/jinsui/tsuki/index.html|url-status=dead|archive-date=2019-06-06|access-date=2021-02-04}}</ref>
* Fallen ] prices: In the case of Japan asset price deflation was a mean reversion or correction back to the price level that prevailed before the asset bubble. There was a rather large ] in ]s and especially ] in Japan in the 1980s (peaking in late 1989).<ref>{{Cite web|last=Nielsen|first=Barry|title=The Lost Decade: Lessons From Japan's Real Estate Crisis|url=https://www.investopedia.com/articles/economics/08/japan-1990s-credit-crunch-liquidity-trap.asp|access-date=2021-02-04|website=Investopedia|language=en}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|last=Post|first=The Blah|date=2019-11-17|title=Japanese Asset Price Bubble|url=https://medium.com/@swatisudhakaran/japanese-asset-price-bubble-48bc1639f666|access-date=2021-02-04|website=Medium|language=en}}</ref>
* Insolvent companies: Banks lent to companies and individuals that invested in real estate. When real estate values dropped, these loans could not be paid. The banks could try to collect on the collateral (land), but this wouldn't pay off the loan. Banks delayed that decision, hoping asset prices would improve. These delays were allowed by national banking regulators. Some banks made even more loans to these companies that are used to service the debt they already had. This continuing process is known as maintaining an "unrealized loss", and until the assets are completely revalued and/or sold off (and the loss realized), it will continue to be a deflationary force in the economy. Improving bankruptcy law, land transfer law, and tax law have been suggested as methods to speed this process and thus end the deflation.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Group|first=Global Legal|title=International Comparative Legal Guides|url=https://iclg.com/practice-areas/restructuring-and-insolvency-laws-and-regulations/japan|access-date=2021-02-04|website=International Comparative Legal Guides International Business Reports|language=en}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|title=Practical Law UK Signon|url=https://signon.thomsonreuters.com/?productid=PLCUK&viewproductid=UKPL&lr=0&culture=en-GB&returnto=https%3a%2f%2fuk.practicallaw.thomsonreuters.com%2fCosi%2fSignOn%3fredirectId%3drt_a4870076-2703-4605-97ff-f08574fb3b5b&tracetoken=0204210942140CvCsgoHJiMwaBw39XiWjYkZf7BuLWKhdD4IKQLRqkuKTNqq0uY7L-SNnb6hW5HJa_sHPQSMcrBJvtle0FRWi-kHms5dRA6MV8ZxXPCuxInbgcBE3ulPDB2z7jH1JUsZlNV_soxJ41jUzrYlUcZ7KaQ8YvWfzC2AXiVHYTeGKljRk8Bf2NxoS7YZVRmexAcKyWC8dnsRYP0pDDfB_ChO0JlUZykNMghFRGv-ye4yf3PPTtEMKJEh8jgl_D3s0C1zCeYs8Sq4HgQxBjl5XvbbK0YqbM7cru3kAM6t9DMvOVqcwdqzT3rq99Oc8xou-BUuB_KnlWcGfZFt6jFLkw2cta7S9D9F-eUxOzifxbSqBOrMjeC5Eza68vFPFsUV1IvRG|access-date=2021-02-04|website=signon.thomsonreuters.com}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|date=2021-01-13|title=Japan's 2020 corporate bankruptcies fall to 31-year low with government aid|url=https://www.japantimes.co.jp/news/2021/01/13/business/corporate-business/japans-2020-corporate-bankruptcies-fall-to-31-year-low-government-aid/|access-date=2021-02-04|website=The Japan Times|language=en-US}}</ref><ref>{{Cite news|date=2002-05-09|title=Prize possessions|newspaper=The Economist|url=https://www.economist.com/finance-and-economics/2002/05/09/prize-possessions|access-date=2021-02-04|issn=0013-0613}}</ref><ref>{{Cite news|date=2020-09-24|title=What to do about zombie firms|newspaper=The Economist|url=https://www.economist.com/leaders/2020/09/24/what-to-do-about-zombie-firms|access-date=2021-02-04|issn=0013-0613}}</ref>
* Insolvent banks: Banks with a larger percentage of their loans which are "non-performing", that is to say, they are not receiving payments on them, but have not yet written them off, cannot lend more money; they must increase their cash reserves to cover the bad loans.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Is the Bank of Japan Technically Insolvent? Dangers Involved in Long-Term Deterioration of BoJ Financial Position {{!}} Discuss Japan-Japan Foreign Policy Forum|url=https://www.japanpolicyforum.jp/economy/pt20180222185219.html|access-date=2021-02-04|website=www.japanpolicyforum.jp|archive-date=2021-02-09|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210209020705/https://www.japanpolicyforum.jp/economy/pt20180222185219.html|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref>{{Cite news|title=Nippon Credit Bank declared insolvent and nationalised|url=https://www.irishtimes.com/business/nippon-credit-bank-declared-insolvent-and-nationalised-1.225394|access-date=2021-02-04|newspaper=The Irish Times|language=en}}</ref>
* Fear of insolvent banks: Japanese people are afraid that banks will collapse so they prefer to buy (United States or Japanese) Treasury bonds instead of saving their money in a bank account. This likewise means the money is not available for lending and therefore economic growth. This means that the savings rate depresses consumption, but does not appear in the economy in an efficient form to spur new investment. People also save by owning real estate, further slowing growth, since it inflates land prices.{{dubious|reason=No reasoning given for how real estate prices slow growth, and this directly contradicts the paragraph above which pins deflation on falling real estate prices and banks hoping for some price increases before they realise their losses.|date=November 2017}}
* Imported deflation: Japan imports Chinese and other countries' inexpensive consumable goods (due to lower wages and fast growth in those countries) and inexpensive raw materials, many of which reached all time real price minimums in the early 2000s. Thus, prices of imported products are decreasing. Domestic producers must match these prices in order to remain competitive. This decreases prices for many things in the economy, and thus is deflationary.<ref>{{Cite web|last=|first=|date=|title=|url=https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/files/wp08-29bk.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140308154019/http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/files/wp08-29bk.pdf |archive-date=2014-03-08 |url-status=live|access-date=|website=}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|title=New Japanese Import! Deflation|url=https://www.bullionvault.com/gold-news/deflation-japan-061720151|access-date=2021-02-04|website=www.bullionvault.com|language=en-US}}</ref>
* Stimulus spending: According to both Austrian and monetarist economic theory, Keynesian stimulus spending actually has a depressing effect. This is because the government is competing against private industry, and usurping private investment dollars.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://butnowyouknow.net/2009/07/15/why-stimulus-spending-depresses-the-economy/|title=Why Stimulus Spending Depresses the Economy|work=But Now You Know|date=16 July 2009}}</ref> In 1998, for example, Japan produced a stimulus package of more than 16 trillion yen, over half of it public works that would have a quashing effect on an equivalent amount of private, wealth-creating economic activity.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://mises.org/daily/1099|title=Explaining Japan's Recession, Benjamin Powell|work=Mises Institute|date=19 November 2002}}</ref> Overall, Japan's stimulus packages added up to over ''one hundred trillion'' yen, and yet they failed. According to these economic schools, that stimulus money actually perpetuated the problem it was intended to cure.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Ponciano|first=Jonathan|title=World Bank Warns Stimulus Spending And 'Dangerous' Debt Crisis Could Trigger Recession And Wipe Out A Decade Of Income Gains|url=https://www.forbes.com/sites/jonathanponciano/2021/01/05/world-bank-warns-stimulus-and-dangerous-debt-crisis-could-trigger-recession-and-wipe-out-a-decade-of-income-gains/|access-date=2021-02-04|website=Forbes|language=en}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|last=Salsman|first=Richard|title=Japan's Three Decades of Depressive Stimulus Schemes – AIER|url=https://www.aier.org/article/japans-three-decades-of-depressive-stimulus-schemes/|access-date=2021-02-04|website=www.aier.org|date=3 June 2020 |language=en-US}}</ref>


In November 2009, Japan returned to deflation, according to '']''. ] reports that consumer prices fell in October 2009 by a near-record 2.2%.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=aKEgYWoMAWIc|title=Japan Releases Stimulus Package as Recovery Weakens (Update3)|website=]|date=16 August 2023 }}</ref> It was not until 2014 that new ] policies laid out by ] ] finally allowed for significant levels of inflation to return.<ref>{{Cite news|date=2014-05-30|title=Japan inflation rate hits 23-year high|language=en-GB|work=BBC News|url=https://www.bbc.com/news/business-27615551|access-date=2021-02-04}}</ref> However, the ] once again led to deflation in 2020, with consumer good prices quickly falling, prompting heavy government stimulus worth over 20% of GDP.<ref>{{Cite web|date=2020-04-06|title=Abe unveils 'massive' coronavirus stimulus worth 20% of GDP|url=https://www.japantimes.co.jp/news/2020/04/06/business/shinzo-abe-japan-massive-coronavirus-stimulus/|access-date=2021-02-04|website=The Japan Times|language=en-US}}</ref><ref>{{Cite news|last=Kihara|first=Kaori Kaneko, Leika|date=2020-12-18|title=Japan's consumer prices fall at fastest pace in decade, stoke deflation fears|language=en|work=Reuters|url=https://www.reuters.com/article/us-japan-economy-inflation-idUKKBN28S05V|access-date=2021-02-04}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|date=2020-05-01|title=Deflation fears reignited as pandemic hits consumer prices in Japan|url=https://www.japantimes.co.jp/news/2020/05/01/business/economy-business/deflation-pandemic-consumer-prices/|access-date=2021-02-04|website=The Japan Times|language=en-US}}</ref> As a result, it is likely that deflation will remain as a long-term economic issue for Japan.<ref>{{Cite web|last=FocusEconomics|title=Japan Inflation Rate (CPI) - Japan Economy Forecast & Outlook|url=https://www.focus-economics.com/country-indicator/japan/inflation|access-date=2021-02-04|website=FocusEconomics {{!}} Economic Forecasts from the World's Leading Economists|language=en}}</ref>
*Insolvent companies: Banks lent to companies and individuals that invested in real estate. When real estate values dropped, these loans could not be paid. The banks could try to collect on the collateral (land), but this wouldn't pay off the loan. Banks have delayed that decision, hoping asset prices would improve. These delays were allowed by national banking regulators. Some banks make even more loans to these companies that are used to service the debt they already have. This continuing process is known as maintaining an "unrealized loss", and until the assets are completely revalued and/or sold off (and the loss realized), it will continue to be a deflationary force in the economy. Improving bankruptcy law, land transfer law, and tax law have been suggested (by the Economist magazine) as methods to speed this process and thus end the deflation.


===United Kingdom===
*Insolvent banks: Banks with a larger percentage of their loans which are "]", that is to say, they are not receiving payments on them, but have not yet written them off, cannot lend more money; they must increase their cash reserves to cover the ].
During ] the ] ] was removed from the gold standard. The motivation for this policy change was to finance World War I; one of the results was inflation, and a rise in the gold price, along with the corresponding drop in international exchange rates for the pound. When the pound was returned to the gold standard after the war it was done on the basis of the pre-war gold price, which, since it was higher than equivalent price in gold, required prices to fall to realign with the higher target value of the pound.


The UK experienced deflation of approximately 10% in 1921, 14% in 1922, and 3 to 5% in the early 1930s.<ref>Bank of England Quarterly inflation report Feb 2009 p. 33 chart A</ref>
*Fear of insolvent banks: Japanese people are afraid that banks will collapse so they prefer to buy gold or (United States or Japanese) Treasury bonds instead of saving their money in a bank account. This likewise means the money is not available for lending and therefore economic growth. This decreases the supply of money available for lending and economic growth. This means that the savings rate depresses consumption, but does not appear in the economy in an efficient form to spur new investment. People also save by owning real estate, further slowing growth, since it inflates land prices.


===United States===
*Imported deflation: Japan imports Chinese and other countries' inexpensive consumable goods, raw materials (due to lower wages and fast growth in those countries). Thus, prices of imported products are decreasing. Domestic producers must match these prices in order to remain competitive. This decreases prices for many things in the economy, and thus is deflationary.
] since 1666]]
] starting from 1913. Source: U.S. Department of Labor]]


====Major deflations in the United States====
==References==
There have been four significant periods of deflation in the United States.
* Ben S. Bernanke, Deflation: Making Sure "It" Doesn't Happen Here, Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke Before the National Economists Club, Washington, D.C.. November 21, 2002

* Michael Bordo & Andrew Filardo, Deflation and monetary policy in a historiscal perspective: remembering the past or being condemned to repeat it?, In: Economic Policy, October 2005, pp 799-844.
The first and most severe was during the depression in 1818–1821 when prices of agricultural commodities declined by almost 50%. A credit contraction caused by a financial crisis in England drained specie out of the U.S. The Bank of the United States also contracted its lending. The price of agricultural commodities fell by almost 50% from the high in 1815 to the low in 1821, and did not recover until the late 1830s, although to a significantly lower price level. Most damaging was the price of cotton, the U.S.'s main export. Food crop prices, which had been high because of the famine of 1816 that was caused by the ], fell after the return of normal harvests in 1818. Improved transportation, mainly from turnpikes, and to a minor extent the introduction of steamboats, significantly lowered transportation costs.<ref name="Taylor 1951">{{cite book |title=The Transportation Revolution, 1815–1860 |last=Taylor |first= George Rogers |year=1951 |publisher = Rinehart & Co. |location=New York |volume=IV |series=The Economic History of the United States |isbn= 978-0-87332-101-3 |pages=133, 331–334 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=qjbLCQAAQBAJ&pg=PP1}}
* Georg Erber, The Risk of Deflation in Germany and the Monetary Policy of the ECB. In: Cesifo Forum 4 (2003), 3, pp 24-29
</ref>
* Charles Goodhart and Boris Hofmann, Deflation, credit and asset prices, In: Deflation - Current and Historical Perspectives, eds. Richard C. K. Burdekin & Pierre L. Siklos, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

* International Monetary Fund, Deflation: Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options - Findings of an Independent Task Force, Washington D. C., April 30, 2003.
The second was the depression of the late 1830s to 1843, following the ], when the currency in the United States contracted by about 34% with prices falling by 33%. The magnitude of this contraction is only matched by the Great Depression.<ref name="Atack1994">{{cite book |title = A New Economic View of American History |last1 = Atack |first1 = Jeremy |last2 = Passell |first2 = Peter |year = 1994 |publisher = W.W. Norton and Co. |location = New York |isbn = 0-393-96315-2 |page = |url-access = registration |url = https://archive.org/details/neweconomicviewo00atac/page/102}}</ref> (See: {{section link|#Historical examples of credit deflation}}.) This "deflation" satisfies both definitions, that of a decrease in prices and a decrease in the available quantity of money. Despite the deflation and depression, GDP rose 16% from 1839 to 1843.<ref name="Atack1994"/>
* International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook 2006 - Globalization and Inflation, Washington D. C., April 2006.

* Otmar Issing, The euro after four years: is there a risk of deflation?, 16th European Finance Convention, 2 December 2002, London, Europäische Zentralbank, Frankfurt am Main
The third was after the ], sometimes called ]. It was possibly spurred by return to a gold standard, retiring paper money printed during the Civil War:
* Paul Krugman, Its Baaaaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap, In: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, (1998), pp 137-205

* Steven B. Kamin, Mario Marazzi & John W. Schindler, Is China "Exporting Deflation"?, International Finance Discussion Papers No. 791, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington D. C. Januar 2004.
{{blockquote|The Great Sag of 1873–96 could be near the top of the list. Its scope was global. It featured cost-cutting and productivity-enhancing technologies. It flummoxed the experts with its persistence, and it resisted attempts by politicians to understand it, let alone reverse it. It delivered a generation's worth of rising bond prices, as well as the usual losses to unwary creditors via defaults and early calls. Between 1875 and 1896, according to ], prices fell in the United States by 1.7% a year, and in Britain by 0.8% a year. |source=''Grant's Interest Rate Observer'', 10 March 2006<ref>{{cite web |title=Inflation, ho! (a primer on deflation) |date=23 May 2003 |author=<!--Staff writer(s); no by-line--> |work=Grant's Interest Rate Observer |url=http://www.grantspub.com/articles/inflation/ |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060228210300/http://www.grantspub.com/articles/inflation/ |archive-date=28 February 2006}}</ref>}}

(Note: ] (1890) gives an account of the period and discusses the great advances in productivity which Wells argues were the cause of the deflation. The productivity gains matched the deflation.<ref>{{cite book
|title=Recent Economic Changes and Their Effect on Production and Distribution of Wealth and Well-Being of Society
|last=Wells
|first=David A.
|year=1890 |publisher= D. Appleton and Co.|location= New York|isbn= 0-543-72474-3 |url= https://archive.org/details/recenteconomicc01wellgoog
}}</ref> Murray Rothbard (2002) gives a similar account.<ref>{{cite book
|title=History of Money and Banking in the United States
|url=https://archive.org/details/historymoneybank00roth_947
|url-access=limited
|last=Rothbard
|first=Murray
|year=2002|publisher= Ludwig Von Mises Institute |isbn= 0-945466-33-1 |pages=–8 }}</ref>)

The fourth was in 1930–1933 when the rate of deflation was approximately 10 percent/year, part of the United States' slide into the ], where banks failed and ] peaked at 25%.

The deflation of the Great Depression occurred partly because there was an enormous contraction of ] (money), ] creating an environment where ] was in frantic demand, and when the ] was supposed to accommodate that demand, it instead contracted the money supply by 30% in enforcement of its new ], so banks failed one by one (because they were unable to meet the sudden demand for cash{{snd}}see ]). From the standpoint of the ] (see above), there was a simultaneous drop both in money supply (credit) and the ] which was so profound that price deflation took hold despite the increases in money supply spurred by the Federal Reserve.

====Minor deflations in the United States====
Throughout the history of the United States, inflation has approached zero and dipped below for short periods of time. This was quite common in the 19th century, and in the 20th century until the permanent abandonment of the gold standard for the ] in 1948. In the past 60 years, the United States has experienced deflation only two times; in 2009 with the Great Recession and in 2015, when the CPI barely broke below 0% at −0.1%.<ref>{{cite news |first=Yuval |last=Rosenberg |title=America Is In Deflation. So What? |work=The Fiscal Times |date=26 February 2015 |url=http://www.thefiscaltimes.com/2015/02/26/America-Deflation-So-What}}</ref>

Some economists believe the United States may have experienced deflation as part of the ]; compare the theory of ]. Consumer prices dropped 1 percent in October 2008. This was the largest one-month fall in prices in the U.S. since at least 1947. That record was again broken in November 2008 with a 1.7% decline. In response, the ] decided to continue cutting interest rates, down to a near-zero range as of December 16, 2008.<ref>{{cite press release |title=FOMC statement |publisher=Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System |date=16 December 2008 |url=http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20081216b.htm}}</ref>

In late 2008 and early 2009, some economists feared the U.S. would enter a deflationary spiral. Economist ] predicted that the United States would enter a deflationary recession, and coined the term "stag-deflation" to describe it.<ref>{{cite web |title=Get Ready For 'Stag-Deflation' |first=Nouriel |last=Roubini |date=30 October 2008 |work=Forbes |url=https://www.forbes.com/2008/10/29/stagnation-recession-deflation-oped-cx_nr_1030roubini.html}}</ref> It was the opposite of ], which was the main fear during the spring and summer of 2008. The United States then began experiencing measurable deflation, steadily decreasing from the first measured deflation of −0.38% in March, to July's deflation rate of −2.10%. On the wage front, in October 2009, the state of ] announced that its state ], which was indexed to inflation, was set to be cut, which would be the first time a state had cut its minimum wage since 1938.<ref>{{cite news |url=http://www.denverpost.com/headlines/ci_13547177 |title=Colorado minimum wage set to fall |first=Aldo |last=Svaldi |work=] |date=13 October 2009}}</ref>


==See also== ==See also==
{{div col}}
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
{{div col end}}

==Notes==
{{reflist|30em}}

==References==
* ], '''The deflationary bias of exit strategies in the EMU countries''', in: '''Review of economic conditions in Italy''', 2-3: 471–93, (2011).
* Ben S. Bernanke. . USA Federal Reserve Board. 2002-11-21. Accessed: 2008-10-17. (Archived by WebCite at https://web.archive.org/web/20081024060408/http://www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2002/20021121/default.htm
* Michael Bordo & Andrew Filardo, Deflation and monetary policy in a historical perspective: Remembering the past or being condemned to repeat it?, In: Economic Policy, October 2005, pp.&nbsp;799–844.
* Georg Erber, The Risk of Deflation in Germany and the Monetary Policy of the ECB. In: Cesifo Forum 4 (2003), 3, pp.&nbsp;24–29
* Charles Goodhart and Boris Hofmann, Deflation, credit and asset prices, In: Deflation - Current and Historical Perspectives, eds. Richard C. K. Burdekin & Pierre L. Siklos, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2004.
* International Monetary Fund, Deflation: Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options - Findings of an Independent Task Force, Washington D. C., April 30, 2003.
* International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook 2006 – Globalization and Inflation, Washington D. C., April 2006.
* Otmar Issing, The euro after four years: is there a risk of deflation?, 16th European Finance Convention, 2 December 2002, London, Europäische Zentralbank, Frankfurt am Main
* Steven B. Kamin, Mario Marazzi & John W. Schindler, Is China "Exporting Deflation"?, International Finance Discussion Papers No. 791, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington D. C. January 2004.
* {{cite journal |first=Paul |last=Krugman |title=Its Baaaaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap |journal=Brookings Papers on Economic Activity |volume=1998 |date=1998 |issue=2 |pages=137–205 |doi=10.2307/2534694 |jstor=2534694 |url=https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/1998/06/1998b_bpea_krugman_dominquez_rogoff.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161203142431/https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/1998/06/1998b_bpea_krugman_dominquez_rogoff.pdf |archive-date=2016-12-03 |url-status=live}}


==External links== ==External links==
{{Wikiquote}}
* ]
* *
* '''' ( ] encyclopedia) * '''' ( ] encyclopedia)
* (About.com) * {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090723002544/http://economics.about.com/cs/inflation/a/deflation.htm |date=2009-07-23 }} (About.com)
* from ''Making Economic Sense'' by ] * from ''Making Economic Sense'' by ]
* {{cite web |url=http://www.euroekonom.com/database/graphs3.php?type=inflation-japan&lang=an&time=0 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080410094942/http://www.euroekonom.com/database/graphs3.php?type=inflation-japan&lang=an&time=0 |archive-date=2008-04-10 |title=Annual Inflation Rate – Japan}}
*


{{Economics}}
]
{{United States – Commonwealth of Nations recessions}}
{{Authority control}}


] ]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]
]

Latest revision as of 12:43, 20 December 2024

Decrease in the general price level of goods and services For other uses, see Deflation (disambiguation). Not to be confused with Disinflation, a slowdown in the inflation rate.
Part of a series on
Macroeconomics
Federal Reserve
Basic concepts
Policies
Models
Related fields
SchoolsMainstream

Heterodox

People
See also

In economics, deflation is a decrease in the general price level of goods and services. Deflation occurs when the inflation rate falls below 0% (a negative inflation rate). Inflation reduces the value of currency over time, but deflation increases it. This allows more goods and services to be bought than before with the same amount of currency. Deflation is distinct from disinflation, a slowdown in the inflation rate; i.e., when inflation declines to a lower rate but is still positive.

Economists generally believe that a sudden deflationary shock is a problem in a modern economy because it increases the real value of debt, especially if the deflation is unexpected. Deflation may also aggravate recessions and lead to a deflationary spiral (see later section).

Some economists argue that prolonged deflationary periods are related to the underlying technological progress in an economy, because as productivity increases (TFP), the cost of goods decreases.

Deflation usually happens when supply is high (when excess production occurs), when demand is low (when consumption decreases), or when the money supply decreases (sometimes in response to a contraction created from careless investment or a credit crunch) or because of a net capital outflow from the economy. It can also occur when there is too much competition and too little market concentration.

Causes and corresponding types

This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (November 2014) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

In the IS–LM model (investment and saving equilibrium – liquidity preference and money supply equilibrium model), deflation is caused by a shift in the supply and demand curve for goods and services. This in turn can be caused by an increase in supply, a fall in demand, or both.

When prices are falling, consumers have an incentive to delay purchases and consumption until prices fall further, which in turn reduces overall economic activity. When purchases are delayed, productive capacity is idled and investment falls, leading to further reductions in aggregate demand. This is the deflationary spiral. The way to reverse this quickly would be to introduce an economic stimulus. The government could increase productive spending on things like infrastructure or the central bank could start expanding the money supply.

Deflation is also related to risk aversion, where investors and buyers will start hoarding money because its value is now increasing over time. This can produce a liquidity trap or it may lead to shortages that entice investments yielding more jobs and commodity production. A central bank cannot, normally, charge negative interest for money, and even charging zero interest often produces less stimulative effect than slightly higher rates of interest. In a closed economy, this is because charging zero interest also means having zero return on government securities, or even negative return on short maturities. In an open economy, it creates a carry trade and devalues the currency. A devalued currency produces higher prices for imports without necessarily stimulating exports to a like degree.

Deflation is the natural condition of economies when the supply of money is fixed, or does not grow as quickly as population and the economy. When this happens, the available amount of hard currency per person falls, in effect making money more scarce, and consequently, the purchasing power of each unit of currency increases. Deflation also occurs when improvements in production efficiency lower the overall price of goods. Competition in the marketplace often prompts those producers to apply at least some portion of these cost savings into reducing the asking price for their goods. When this happens, consumers pay less for those goods, and consequently, deflation has occurred, since purchasing power has increased.

Rising productivity and reduced transportation cost created structural deflation during the accelerated productivity era from 1870 to 1900, but there was mild inflation for about a decade before the establishment of the Federal Reserve in 1913. There was inflation during World War I, but deflation returned again after the war and during the 1930s depression. Most nations abandoned the gold standard in the 1930s so that there is less reason to expect deflation, aside from the collapse of speculative asset classes, under a fiat monetary system with low productivity growth.

CPI 1914-2022
American CPI 1914-2022  Inflation   Deflation   M2 money supply increases year/year

In mainstream economics, deflation may be caused by a combination of the supply and demand for goods and the supply and demand for money, specifically the supply of money going down and the supply of goods going up. Historic episodes of deflation have often been associated with the supply of goods going up (due to increased productivity) without an increase in the supply of money, or (as with the Great Depression and possibly Japan in the early 1990s) the demand for goods going down combined with a decrease in the money supply. Studies of the Great Depression by Ben Bernanke have indicated that, in response to decreased demand, the Federal Reserve of the time decreased the money supply, hence contributing to deflation.

Causes include, on the demand side:

  • Growth deflation
  • Hoarding

And on the supply side:

  • Bank credit deflation
  • Debt deflation
  • Decision on the money supply side
  • Credit deflation

Growth deflation

Growth deflation is an enduring decrease in the real cost of goods and services as the result of technological progress, accompanied by competitive price cuts, resulting in an increase in aggregate demand.

A structural deflation existed from the 1870s until the cycle upswing that started in 1895. The deflation was caused by the decrease in the production and distribution costs of goods. It resulted in competitive price cuts when markets were oversupplied. The mild inflation after 1895 was attributed to the increase in gold supply that had been occurring for decades. There was a sharp rise in prices during World War I, but deflation returned at the war's end. By contrast, under a fiat monetary system, there was high productivity growth from the end of World War II until the 1960s, but no deflation.

Historically not all episodes of deflation correspond with periods of poor economic growth.

Productivity and deflation are discussed in a 1940 study by the Brookings Institution that gives productivity by major US industries from 1919 to 1939, along with real and nominal wages. Persistent deflation was clearly understood as being the result of the enormous gains in productivity of the period. By the late 1920s, most goods were over supplied, which contributed to high unemployment during the Great Depression.

Bank credit deflation

Bank credit deflation is a decrease in the bank credit supply due to bank failures or increased perceived risk of defaults by private entities or a contraction of the money supply by the central bank.

Debt deflation

Main article: Debt deflation

Debt deflation is a complicated phenomenon associated with the end of long-term credit cycles. It was proposed as a theory by Irving Fisher (1933) to explain the deflation of the Great Depression.

Money supply-side deflation

From a monetarist perspective, deflation is caused primarily by a reduction in the velocity of money or the amount of money supply per person.

A historical analysis of money velocity and monetary base shows an inverse correlation: for a given percentage decrease in the monetary base the result is a nearly equal percentage increase in money velocity. This is to be expected because monetary base (MB), velocity of base money (VB), price level (P) and real output (Y) are related by definition: MBVB = PY. However, the monetary base is a much narrower definition of money than M2 money supply. Additionally, the velocity of the monetary base is interest-rate sensitive, the highest velocity being at the highest interest rates.

In the early history of the United States, there was no national currency and an insufficient supply of coinage. Banknotes were the majority of the money in circulation. During financial crises, many banks failed and their notes became worthless. Also, banknotes were discounted relative to gold and silver, the discount depended on the financial strength of the bank.

In recent years changes in the money supply have historically taken a long time to show up in the price level, with a rule of thumb lag of at least 18 months. More recently Alan Greenspan cited the time lag as taking between 12 and 13 quarters. Bonds, equities and commodities have been suggested as reservoirs for buffering changes in the money supply.

Credit deflation

In modern credit-based economies, deflation may be caused by the central bank initiating higher interest rates (i.e., to "control" inflation), thereby possibly popping an asset bubble. In a credit-based economy, a slow-down or fall in lending leads to less money in circulation, with a further sharp fall in money supply as confidence reduces and velocity weakens, with a consequent sharp fall-off in demand for employment or goods. The fall in demand causes a fall in prices as a supply glut develops. This becomes a deflationary spiral when prices fall below the costs of financing production, or repaying debt levels incurred at the prior price level. Businesses, unable to make enough profit no matter how low they set prices, are then liquidated. Banks get assets that have fallen dramatically in value since their mortgage loan was made, and if they sell those assets, they further glut supply, which only exacerbates the situation. To slow or halt the deflationary spiral, banks will often withhold collecting on non-performing loans (as in Japan, and most recently America and Spain). This is often no more than a stop-gap measure, because they must then restrict credit, since they do not have money to lend, which further reduces demand, and so on.

Historical examples of credit deflation

In the early economic history of the United States, cycles of inflation and deflation correlated with capital flows between regions, with money being loaned from the financial center in the Northeast to the commodity producing regions of the (mid)-West and South. In a procyclical manner, prices of commodities rose when capital was flowing in, that is, when banks were willing to lend, and fell in the depression years of 1818 and 1839 when banks called in loans. Also, there was no national paper currency at the time and there was a scarcity of coins. Most money circulated as banknotes, which typically sold at a discount according to distance from the issuing bank and the bank's perceived financial strength.

When banks failed their notes were redeemed for bank reserves, which often did not result in payment at par value, and sometimes the notes became worthless. Notes of weak surviving banks traded at steep discounts. During the Great Depression, people who owed money to a bank whose deposits had been frozen would sometimes buy bank books (deposits of other people at the bank) at a discount and use them to pay off their debt at par value.

Deflation occurred periodically in the U.S. during the 19th century (the most important exception was during the Civil War). This deflation was at times caused by technological progress that created significant economic growth, but at other times it was triggered by financial crises – notably the Panic of 1837 which caused deflation through 1844, and the Panic of 1873 which triggered the Long Depression that lasted until 1879. These deflationary periods preceded the establishment of the U.S. Federal Reserve System and its active management of monetary matters. Episodes of deflation have been rare and brief since the Federal Reserve was created (a notable exception being the Great Depression) while U.S. economic progress has been unprecedented.

A financial crisis in England in 1818 caused banks to call in loans and curtail new lending, draining specie out of the U.S. The Bank of the United States also reduced its lending. Prices for cotton and tobacco fell. The price of agricultural commodities also was pressured by a return of normal harvests following 1816, the year without a summer, that caused large scale famine and high agricultural prices.

There were several causes of the deflation of the severe depression of 1839–1843, which included an oversupply of agricultural commodities (importantly cotton) as new cropland came into production following large federal land sales a few years earlier, banks requiring payment in gold or silver, the failure of several banks, default by several states on their bonds and British banks cutting back on specie flow to the U.S.

This cycle has been traced out on a broad scale during the Great Depression. Partly because of overcapacity and market saturation and partly as a result of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act, international trade contracted sharply, severely reducing demand for goods, thereby idling a great deal of capacity, and setting off a string of bank failures. A similar situation in Japan, beginning with the stock and real estate market collapse in the early 1990s, was arrested by the Japanese government preventing the collapse of most banks and taking over direct control of several in the worst condition.

Scarcity of official money

The United States had no national paper money until 1862 (greenbacks used to fund the Civil War), but these notes were discounted to gold until 1877. There was also a shortage of U.S. minted coins. Foreign coins, such as Mexican silver, were commonly used. At times banknotes were as much as 80% of currency in circulation before the Civil War. In the financial crises of 1818–19 and 1837–1841, many banks failed, leaving their money to be redeemed below par value from reserves. Sometimes the notes became worthless, and the notes of weak surviving banks were heavily discounted. The Jackson administration opened branch mints, which over time increased the supply of coins. Following the 1848 finding of gold in the Sierra Nevada, enough gold came to market to devalue gold relative to silver. To equalize the value of the two metals in coinage, the US mint slightly reduced the silver content of new coinage in 1853.

When structural deflation appeared in the years following 1870, a common explanation given by various government inquiry committees was a scarcity of gold and silver, although they usually mentioned the changes in industry and trade we now call productivity. However, David A. Wells (1890) notes that the U.S. money supply during the period 1879-1889 actually rose 60%, the increase being in gold and silver, which rose against the percentage of national bank and legal tender notes. Furthermore, Wells argued that the deflation only lowered the cost of goods that benefited from recent improved methods of manufacturing and transportation. Goods produced by craftsmen did not decrease in price, nor did many services, and the cost of labor actually increased. Also, deflation did not occur in countries that did not have modern manufacturing, transportation and communications.

By the end of the 19th century, deflation ended and turned to mild inflation. William Stanley Jevons predicted rising gold supply would cause inflation decades before it actually did. Irving Fisher blamed the worldwide inflation of the pre-WWI years on rising gold supply.

In economies with an unstable currency, barter and other alternate currency arrangements such as dollarization are common, and therefore when the 'official' money becomes scarce (or unusually unreliable), commerce can still continue (e.g., most recently in Zimbabwe). Since in such economies the central government is often unable, even if it were willing, to adequately control the internal economy, there is no pressing need for individuals to acquire official currency except to pay for imported goods.

Currency pegs and monetary unions

If a country pegs its currency to one of another country that features a higher productivity growth or a more favourable unit cost development, it must – to maintain its competitiveness – either become equally more productive or lower its factor prices (e.g., wages). Cutting factor prices fosters deflation. Monetary unions have a similar effect to currency pegs.

Effects

This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.
Find sources: "Deflation" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (September 2022) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

On spending and borrowing

Some believe that, in the absence of large amounts of debt, deflation would be a welcome effect because the lowering of prices increases purchasing power. However, while an increase in the purchasing power of one's money benefits some, it amplifies the sting of debt for others: after a period of deflation, the payments to service a debt represent a larger amount of purchasing power than they did when the debt was first incurred. Consequently, deflation can be thought of as an effective increase in a loan's interest rate. If, as during the Great Depression in the United States, deflation averages 10% per year, even an interest-free loan is unattractive as it must be repaid with money worth 10% more each year.

Under normal conditions, most central banks, such as the Federal Reserve, implement policy by setting a target for a short-term interest rate – the overnight federal funds rate in the U.S. – and enforcing that target by buying and selling securities in open capital markets. When the short-term interest rate hits zero, the central bank can no longer ease policy by lowering its usual interest-rate target. With interest rates near zero, debt relief becomes an increasingly important tool in managing deflation.

In recent times, as loan terms have grown in length and loan financing (or leveraging) is common among many types of investments, the costs of deflation to borrowers has grown larger.

On savings and investments

Deflation can discourage private investment, because there is reduced expectations on future profits when future prices are lower. Consequently, with reduced private investments, spiraling deflation can cause a collapse in aggregate demand. Without the "hidden risk of inflation", it may become more prudent for institutions to hold on to money, and not to spend or invest it (burying money). They are therefore rewarded by saving and holding money. This "hoarding" behavior is seen as undesirable by most economists. Friedrich Hayek, a libertarian Austrian-school economist, wrote that:

It is agreed that hoarding money, whether in cash or in idle balances, is deflationary in its effects. No one thinks that deflation is in itself desirable.

— Hayek (1932)

Compared with inflation

Deflation causes a transfer of wealth from borrowers and holders of illiquid assets to the benefit of savers and of holders of liquid assets and currency, and because confused price signals cause malinvestment in the form of underinvestment. In this sense, its effects are the opposite of inflation, the effect of which is to transfer wealth from currency holders and lenders (savers) and to borrowers, including governments, and cause overinvestment. Whereas inflation encourages short term consumption and can similarly overstimulate investment in projects that may not be worthwhile in real terms (for example, the dot-com and housing bubbles), deflation reduces investment even when there is a real-world demand not being met. In modern economies, deflation is usually associated with economic depression, as occurred in the Great Depression and the Long Depression. Deflation was present during most economic depressions in US history.

Deflationary spiral

A deflationary spiral is a situation where decreases in the price level lead to lower production, which in turn leads to lower wages and demand, which leads to further decreases in the price level. Since reductions in general price level are called deflation, a deflationary spiral occurs when reductions in price lead to a vicious circle, where a problem exacerbates its own cause. In science, this effect is also known as a positive feedback loop. Another economic example of this situation in economics is the bank run.

The Great Depression was regarded by some as a deflationary spiral. A deflationary spiral is the modern macroeconomic version of the general glut controversy of the 19th century. Another related idea is Irving Fisher's theory that excess debt can cause a continuing deflation.

Counteracting deflation

During severe deflation, targeting an interest rate (the usual method of determining how much currency to create) may be ineffective, because even lowering the short-term interest rate to zero may result in a real interest rate which is too high to attract credit-worthy borrowers. In the 21st-century, negative interest rates have been tried, but it cannot be too negative, since people might withdraw cash from bank accounts if they have a negative interest rate. Thus the central bank must directly set a target for the quantity of money (called "quantitative easing") and may use extraordinary methods to increase the supply of money, e.g. purchasing financial assets of a type not usually used by the central bank as reserves (such as mortgage-backed securities). Before he was Chairman of the United States Federal Reserve, Ben Bernanke claimed in 2002, "sufficient injections of money will ultimately always reverse a deflation", although Japan's deflationary spiral was not broken by the amount of quantitative easing provided by the Bank of Japan.

Until the 1930s, it was commonly believed by economists that deflation would cure itself. As prices decreased, demand would naturally increase, and the economic system would correct itself without outside intervention.

This view was challenged in the 1930s during the Great Depression. Keynesian economists argued that the economic system was not self-correcting with respect to deflation and that governments and central banks had to take active measures to boost demand through tax cuts or increases in government spending. Reserve requirements from the central bank were high compared to recent times. So were it not for redemption of currency for gold (in accordance with the gold standard), the central bank could have effectively increased money supply by simply reducing the reserve requirements and through open market operations (e.g., buying treasury bonds for cash) to offset the reduction of money supply in the private sectors due to the collapse of credit (credit is a form of money).

With the rise of monetarist ideas, the focus in fighting deflation was put on expanding demand by lowering interest rates (i.e., reducing the "cost" of money). This view has received criticism in light of the failure of accommodative policies in both Japan and the US to spur demand after stock market shocks in the early 1990s and in 2000–2002, respectively. Austrian economists worry about the inflationary impact of monetary policies on asset prices. Sustained low real rates can cause higher asset prices and excessive debt accumulation. Therefore, lowering rates may prove to be only a temporary palliative, aggravating an eventual debt deflation crisis.

Special borrowing arrangements

When the central bank has lowered nominal interest rates to zero, it can no longer further stimulate demand by lowering interest rates. This is the famous liquidity trap. When deflation takes hold, it requires "special arrangements" to lend money at a zero nominal rate of interest (which could still be a very high real rate of interest, due to the negative inflation rate) in order to artificially increase the money supply.

Capital

Although the values of capital assets are often casually said to deflate when they decline, this usage is not consistent with the usual definition of deflation; a more accurate description for a decrease in the value of a capital asset is economic depreciation. Another term, the accounting conventions of depreciation are standards to determine a decrease in values of capital assets when market values are not readily available or practical.

Historical examples

This article appears to be slanted towards recent events. In particular, Examples are generally in reverse chronological order, while the case of the Spanish Empire among other highly notable ones isn’t even mentioned. Rather egregious. Please try to keep recent events in historical perspective and add more content related to non-recent events. (December 2024)

EU countries

The inflation rate of Greece was negative during three years from 2013 to 2015. The same applies to Bulgaria, Cyprus, Spain, and Slovakia from 2014 to 2016. Greece, Cyprus, Spain, and Slovakia are members of the European monetary union. The Bulgarian currency, the lev, is pegged to the Euro with a fixed exchange rate. In the entire European Union and the Eurozone, a disinflationary development was to be observed in the years 2011 to 2015.

Year Bulgaria Greece Cyprus Spain Slovakia EU Eurozone
2011 3.4 3.1 3.5 3.0 4.1 3.1 2.7
2012 2.4 1.0 3.1 2.4 3.7 2.6 2.5
2013 0.4 −0.9 0.4 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.4
2014 −1.6 −1.4 −0.3 −0.2 −0.1 0.6 0.4
2015 −1.1 −1.1 −1.5 −0.6 −0.3 0.1 0.2
2016 −1.3 0.0 −1.2 −0.3 −0.5 0.2 0.2
2017 1.2 1.1 0.7 2.0 1.4 1.7 1.5

Table: Harmonised index of consumer prices. Annual average rate of change (%) (HICP inflation rate). Negative values are highlighted in colour.

Hong Kong

Following the Asian financial crisis in late 1997, Hong Kong experienced a long period of deflation which did not end until the fourth quarter of 2004. Many East Asian currencies devalued following the crisis. The Hong Kong dollar, however, was pegged to the U.S. dollar, leading to an adjustment instead by a deflation of consumer prices. The situation was worsened by the increasingly cheap exports from mainland China, and "weak consumer confidence" in Hong Kong. This deflation was accompanied by an economic slump that was more severe and prolonged than those of the surrounding countries that devalued their currencies in the wake of the Asian financial crisis.

Ireland

In February 2009, Ireland's Central Statistics Office announced that during January 2009, the country experienced deflation, with prices falling by 0.1% from the same time in 2008. This was the first time deflation has hit the Irish economy since 1960. Overall consumer prices decreased by 1.7% in the month.

Brian Lenihan, Ireland's Minister for Finance, mentioned deflation in an interview with RTÉ Radio. According to RTÉ's account, "Minister for Finance Brian Lenihan has said that deflation must be taken into account when Budget cuts in child benefit, public sector pay and professional fees are being considered. Mr Lenihan said month-on-month there has been a 6.6% decline in the cost of living this year."

This interview is notable in that the deflation referred to is not discernibly regarded negatively by the Minister in the interview. The Minister mentions the deflation as an item of data helpful to the arguments for a cut in certain benefits. The alleged economic harm caused by deflation is not alluded to or mentioned by this member of government. This is a notable example of deflation in the modern era being discussed by a senior financial Minister without any mention of how it might be avoided, or whether it should be.

Japan

This section needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this section. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (September 2010) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

Deflation started in the early 1990s. The Bank of Japan and the government tried to eliminate it by reducing interest rates and "quantitative easing," but did not create a sustained increase in broad money and deflation persisted. In July 2006, the zero-rate policy was ended.

Systemic reasons for deflation in Japan can be said to include:

  • Tight monetary conditions: The Bank of Japan kept monetary policy loose only when inflation was below zero, tightening whenever deflation ends.
  • Unfavorable demographics: Japan has an aging population (22.6% over age 65) which has been declining since 2011, as the death rate exceeds the birth rate.
  • Fallen asset prices: In the case of Japan asset price deflation was a mean reversion or correction back to the price level that prevailed before the asset bubble. There was a rather large price bubble in stocks and especially real estate in Japan in the 1980s (peaking in late 1989).
  • Insolvent companies: Banks lent to companies and individuals that invested in real estate. When real estate values dropped, these loans could not be paid. The banks could try to collect on the collateral (land), but this wouldn't pay off the loan. Banks delayed that decision, hoping asset prices would improve. These delays were allowed by national banking regulators. Some banks made even more loans to these companies that are used to service the debt they already had. This continuing process is known as maintaining an "unrealized loss", and until the assets are completely revalued and/or sold off (and the loss realized), it will continue to be a deflationary force in the economy. Improving bankruptcy law, land transfer law, and tax law have been suggested as methods to speed this process and thus end the deflation.
  • Insolvent banks: Banks with a larger percentage of their loans which are "non-performing", that is to say, they are not receiving payments on them, but have not yet written them off, cannot lend more money; they must increase their cash reserves to cover the bad loans.
  • Fear of insolvent banks: Japanese people are afraid that banks will collapse so they prefer to buy (United States or Japanese) Treasury bonds instead of saving their money in a bank account. This likewise means the money is not available for lending and therefore economic growth. This means that the savings rate depresses consumption, but does not appear in the economy in an efficient form to spur new investment. People also save by owning real estate, further slowing growth, since it inflates land prices.
  • Imported deflation: Japan imports Chinese and other countries' inexpensive consumable goods (due to lower wages and fast growth in those countries) and inexpensive raw materials, many of which reached all time real price minimums in the early 2000s. Thus, prices of imported products are decreasing. Domestic producers must match these prices in order to remain competitive. This decreases prices for many things in the economy, and thus is deflationary.
  • Stimulus spending: According to both Austrian and monetarist economic theory, Keynesian stimulus spending actually has a depressing effect. This is because the government is competing against private industry, and usurping private investment dollars. In 1998, for example, Japan produced a stimulus package of more than 16 trillion yen, over half of it public works that would have a quashing effect on an equivalent amount of private, wealth-creating economic activity. Overall, Japan's stimulus packages added up to over one hundred trillion yen, and yet they failed. According to these economic schools, that stimulus money actually perpetuated the problem it was intended to cure.

In November 2009, Japan returned to deflation, according to The Wall Street Journal. Bloomberg L.P. reports that consumer prices fell in October 2009 by a near-record 2.2%. It was not until 2014 that new economic policies laid out by Prime Minister Shinzo Abe finally allowed for significant levels of inflation to return. However, the COVID-19 recession once again led to deflation in 2020, with consumer good prices quickly falling, prompting heavy government stimulus worth over 20% of GDP. As a result, it is likely that deflation will remain as a long-term economic issue for Japan.

United Kingdom

During World War I the British pound sterling was removed from the gold standard. The motivation for this policy change was to finance World War I; one of the results was inflation, and a rise in the gold price, along with the corresponding drop in international exchange rates for the pound. When the pound was returned to the gold standard after the war it was done on the basis of the pre-war gold price, which, since it was higher than equivalent price in gold, required prices to fall to realign with the higher target value of the pound.

The UK experienced deflation of approximately 10% in 1921, 14% in 1922, and 3 to 5% in the early 1930s.

United States

Annual inflation (in blue) and deflation (in green) rates in the United States since 1666
US CPI-U starting from 1913. Source: U.S. Department of Labor

Major deflations in the United States

There have been four significant periods of deflation in the United States.

The first and most severe was during the depression in 1818–1821 when prices of agricultural commodities declined by almost 50%. A credit contraction caused by a financial crisis in England drained specie out of the U.S. The Bank of the United States also contracted its lending. The price of agricultural commodities fell by almost 50% from the high in 1815 to the low in 1821, and did not recover until the late 1830s, although to a significantly lower price level. Most damaging was the price of cotton, the U.S.'s main export. Food crop prices, which had been high because of the famine of 1816 that was caused by the year without a summer, fell after the return of normal harvests in 1818. Improved transportation, mainly from turnpikes, and to a minor extent the introduction of steamboats, significantly lowered transportation costs.

The second was the depression of the late 1830s to 1843, following the Panic of 1837, when the currency in the United States contracted by about 34% with prices falling by 33%. The magnitude of this contraction is only matched by the Great Depression. (See: § Historical examples of credit deflation.) This "deflation" satisfies both definitions, that of a decrease in prices and a decrease in the available quantity of money. Despite the deflation and depression, GDP rose 16% from 1839 to 1843.

The third was after the Civil War, sometimes called The Great Deflation. It was possibly spurred by return to a gold standard, retiring paper money printed during the Civil War:

The Great Sag of 1873–96 could be near the top of the list. Its scope was global. It featured cost-cutting and productivity-enhancing technologies. It flummoxed the experts with its persistence, and it resisted attempts by politicians to understand it, let alone reverse it. It delivered a generation's worth of rising bond prices, as well as the usual losses to unwary creditors via defaults and early calls. Between 1875 and 1896, according to Milton Friedman, prices fell in the United States by 1.7% a year, and in Britain by 0.8% a year.

— Grant's Interest Rate Observer, 10 March 2006

(Note: David A. Wells (1890) gives an account of the period and discusses the great advances in productivity which Wells argues were the cause of the deflation. The productivity gains matched the deflation. Murray Rothbard (2002) gives a similar account.)

The fourth was in 1930–1933 when the rate of deflation was approximately 10 percent/year, part of the United States' slide into the Great Depression, where banks failed and unemployment peaked at 25%.

The deflation of the Great Depression occurred partly because there was an enormous contraction of credit (money), bankruptcies creating an environment where cash was in frantic demand, and when the Federal Reserve was supposed to accommodate that demand, it instead contracted the money supply by 30% in enforcement of its new real bills doctrine, so banks failed one by one (because they were unable to meet the sudden demand for cash – see Bank run). From the standpoint of the Fisher equation (see above), there was a simultaneous drop both in money supply (credit) and the velocity of money which was so profound that price deflation took hold despite the increases in money supply spurred by the Federal Reserve.

Minor deflations in the United States

Throughout the history of the United States, inflation has approached zero and dipped below for short periods of time. This was quite common in the 19th century, and in the 20th century until the permanent abandonment of the gold standard for the Bretton Woods system in 1948. In the past 60 years, the United States has experienced deflation only two times; in 2009 with the Great Recession and in 2015, when the CPI barely broke below 0% at −0.1%.

Some economists believe the United States may have experienced deflation as part of the financial crisis of 2007–2008; compare the theory of debt deflation. Consumer prices dropped 1 percent in October 2008. This was the largest one-month fall in prices in the U.S. since at least 1947. That record was again broken in November 2008 with a 1.7% decline. In response, the Federal Reserve decided to continue cutting interest rates, down to a near-zero range as of December 16, 2008.

In late 2008 and early 2009, some economists feared the U.S. would enter a deflationary spiral. Economist Nouriel Roubini predicted that the United States would enter a deflationary recession, and coined the term "stag-deflation" to describe it. It was the opposite of stagflation, which was the main fear during the spring and summer of 2008. The United States then began experiencing measurable deflation, steadily decreasing from the first measured deflation of −0.38% in March, to July's deflation rate of −2.10%. On the wage front, in October 2009, the state of Colorado announced that its state minimum wage, which was indexed to inflation, was set to be cut, which would be the first time a state had cut its minimum wage since 1938.

See also

Notes

  1. Robert J. Barro and Vittorio Grilli (1994), European Macroeconomics, chap. 8, p. 142. ISBN 0-333-57764-7
  2. O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 343. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.
  3. Harry Wallop, Harry Wallop (18 November 2008). "Deflation: why it is dangerous". The Daily Telegraph. Archived from the original on 2022-01-12. Retrieved 20 September 2016.
  4. "The Economist explains: Why deflation is bad". Economist. Economist magazine. 7 Jan 2015. Retrieved 20 September 2016.
  5. Krugman, Paul (2 August 2010). "Why is Deflation Bad?". The New York Times. Retrieved 20 September 2016.
  6. Walker, Andrew (29 January 2016). "Is deflation such a bad thing?". BBC. Retrieved 20 September 2016.
  7. Thoma, Mark (8 April 2014). "Explainer: Why is deflation so harmful?". Moneywatch. CBS. Retrieved 20 September 2016.
  8. Hummel, Jeffrey Rogers. "Death and Taxes, Including Inflation: the Public versus Economists" (January 2007). Archived 2009-03-25 at the Wayback Machine
  9. Blanchard, O.; Dell'Ariccia, G.; Mauro, P. (18 August 2010). "Rethinking macroeconomic policy". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 42 (1): 199–215. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.153.7293. doi:10.1111/j.1538-4616.2010.00334.x. S2CID 14824203.
  10. Bordo, Michael D.; Filardo, Andrew J. (2005-11-01). "Deflation in a Historical Perspective" (PDF). Rochester, NY. doi:10.2139/ssrn.860404. S2CID 153344185. SSRN 860404. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  11. "What Causes Negative Inflation (Deflation)?".
  12. "Market Models: Pure Competition, Monopolistic Competition, Oligopoly, and Pure Monopoly".
  13. Hicks, J. R. (1937). "Mr. Keynes and the "Classics"; A Suggested Interpretation". Econometrica. 5 (2): 147–159. doi:10.2307/1907242. JSTOR 1907242.
  14. Meade, J. E. (1937). "A Simplified Model of Mr. Keynes' System". The Review of Economic Studies. 4 (2): 98–107. doi:10.2307/2967607. JSTOR 2967607.
  15. ^ Blanchard, Olivier (2021). Macroeconomics (8th ed.). London: Pearson. ISBN 978-0-13-489789-9.
  16. ^ Hussman, John O. (2010). "Bernanke Leaps into a Liquidity Trap".
  17. ^ Wells, David A. (1890). "Money supply". Recent Economic Changes and Their Effect on Production and Distribution of Wealth and Well-Being of Society. New York: D. Appleton and Co. p. 222. ISBN 0-543-72474-3.
  18. Beckworth, David. "Aggregate Supply-Driven Deflation and Its Implications for Macroeconomic Stability" (PDF). Cato Journal. 28 (3). Cato Institute. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2011-10-09.
  19. Stapleford, Thomas (2009). The Cost of Living in America: A Political History of Economic Statistics, 1880-2000. Cambridge University Peess. pp. 69–73.
  20. Kendrick, John (1991). "U.S. Productivity Performance in Perspective, Business Economics, October 1, 1991". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  21. Andrew Atkeson and Patrick J. Kehoe of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Deflation and Depression: Is There an Empirical Link? Archived 2016-05-06 at the Wayback Machine
  22. Bell, Spurgeon (1940). Productivity, Wages and National Income, The Institute of Economics of the Brookings Institution. Waverly press.
  23. ^ Beaudreau, Bernard C. (1996). Mass Production, the Stock Market Crash and the Great Depression. New York, Lincoln, Shanghi: Authors Choice Press.
  24. Carapella, Francesca (2015). "Banking panics and deflation in dynamic general equilibrium". Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2015-018. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. doi:10.17016/FEDS.2015.018.
  25. Fisher, Irving (October 1933). "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions". Fraser. St Louis, Missouri: Federal Reserve.
  26. Friedman, Milton (1994). Money Mischief: Episodes in Monetary History. Houghton Mifflin Harcourt. p. 38. ISBN 9780547542225.
  27. ^ Ginsburg, David (2006). Gold Coins of the New Orleans Mint: How Gold Coins Circulated in 19th Century America. Zyrus Press. pp. 25–33. ISBN 9780974237169.
  28. ^ Taylor, George Rogers (1951). The Transportation Revolution, 1815–1860. The Economic History of the United States. Vol. IV. New York: Rinehart & Co. pp. 133, 331–334. ISBN 978-0-87332-101-3.
  29. Greenspan interview on CNBC, 3 December 2010
  30. Browne, Harry (1981). You Can Profit from a Monetary Crisis. Ishi Press International. ISBN 4-87187-322-6.
  31. ^ North, Douglas C. (1966). The Economic Growth of the United States 1790–1860. New York, London: W. W. Norton & Company. ISBN 978-0-393-00346-8.
  32. Benjamin Roth, ed. James Ledbetter and Daniel B. Roth, The Great Depression: A Diary. Perseus Books, 2009, p. 36. "A market for buying bank 'passbooks' also cropped up in places like Youngstown. If you were desperate enough in 1931 for money to buy basic necessities, you could get 60 to 70 cents on the dollar for your passbooks' value. Local newspapers even printed the weekly rates for buying and selling these passbooks as they became a commodity; Roth pasted one such rate chart into his diary."
  33. Taylor 1951, pp. 336
  34. Wallis, Hohn Joseph; National Bureau of Economic Research. "The Depression of 1839 to 1843" (PDF).
  35. Stapleford, Thomas (2009). The Cost of Living in America: A Political History of Economic Statistics, 1880–2000. Cambridge University Press. pp. 69–73.
  36. Selgin, George (1997). "Less Than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy" (PDF). IEA Hobart Paper. 32. London: Institute of Economic Affairs: 87. ISSN 0073-2818. Retrieved 4 December 2014.
  37. "Hayek's 1932 Letter on the Great Depression". But Now You Know. 25 November 2010.
  38. "The History of Economic Downturns in the US". But Now You Know. 6 December 2008.
  39. "DEFLATIONARY SPIRALS".
  40. ^ Grinin, L. E., & Korotayev, A. V. (2018). The future of the global economy in the light of inflationary and deflationary trends and long cycles theory. World Futures, 74(2), 84-103 Archived 2020-11-12 at the Wayback Machine.
  41. Kagan, Julia. "Deflationary Spiral". Investopedia. Retrieved 20 March 2021.
  42. "Economics A-Z terms beginning with D". The Economist.
  43. "Deflation: Making Sure 'It' Doesn't Happen Here" Archived 2008-10-24 at the Wayback Machine. Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke before the National Economists Club, Washington, D.C., November 21, 2002. Federal Reserve.
  44. "HICP - inflation rate". Eurostat. Retrieved 8 February 2021.
  45. Archived March 8, 2005, at the Wayback Machine
  46. Jao, Y. C. (2001). "Why Was Hong Kong a Laggard in Economic Recovery". The Asian Financial Crisis and the Ordeal of Hong Kong. Quorum Books. pp. 155–170. ISBN 978-1-56720-447-6.
  47. Liu, Henry C. K. (2003-07-04). "Why Hong Kong is in crisis". Asia Times. Archived from the original on 2003-07-08. Retrieved 27 April 2010.
  48. "First annual negative inflation in 49 years". RTE.ie. 12 February 2009.
  49. Deflation a factor in Budget cuts - Lenihan Archived 2018-09-03 at the Wayback Machine, RTE News, 9 December 2009
  50. RTÉ News - Deflation a factor in Budget cuts - Lenihan Archived February 26, 2010, at the Wayback Machine
  51. "Meet the new BOJ, same as the old BOJ". TheMoneyIllusion. 2010-10-05. Retrieved 2013-02-14.
  52. Dooley, Ben (2019-12-24). "Japan Shrinks by 500,000 People as Births Fall to Lowest Number Since 1874 (Published 2019)". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  53. "Statistics Bureau Home Page/Population Estimates Monthly Report". 2019-06-06. Archived from the original on 2019-06-06. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  54. Nielsen, Barry. "The Lost Decade: Lessons From Japan's Real Estate Crisis". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  55. Post, The Blah (2019-11-17). "Japanese Asset Price Bubble". Medium. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  56. Group, Global Legal. "International Comparative Legal Guides". International Comparative Legal Guides International Business Reports. Retrieved 2021-02-04. {{cite web}}: |last= has generic name (help)
  57. "Practical Law UK Signon". signon.thomsonreuters.com. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  58. "Japan's 2020 corporate bankruptcies fall to 31-year low with government aid". The Japan Times. 2021-01-13. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  59. "Prize possessions". The Economist. 2002-05-09. ISSN 0013-0613. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  60. "What to do about zombie firms". The Economist. 2020-09-24. ISSN 0013-0613. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  61. "Is the Bank of Japan Technically Insolvent? Dangers Involved in Long-Term Deterioration of BoJ Financial Position | Discuss Japan-Japan Foreign Policy Forum". www.japanpolicyforum.jp. Archived from the original on 2021-02-09. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  62. "Nippon Credit Bank declared insolvent and nationalised". The Irish Times. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  63. https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/files/wp08-29bk.pdf. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2014-03-08. {{cite web}}: Missing or empty |title= (help)
  64. "New Japanese Import! Deflation". www.bullionvault.com. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  65. "Why Stimulus Spending Depresses the Economy". But Now You Know. 16 July 2009.
  66. "Explaining Japan's Recession, Benjamin Powell". Mises Institute. 19 November 2002.
  67. Ponciano, Jonathan. "World Bank Warns Stimulus Spending And 'Dangerous' Debt Crisis Could Trigger Recession And Wipe Out A Decade Of Income Gains". Forbes. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  68. Salsman, Richard (3 June 2020). "Japan's Three Decades of Depressive Stimulus Schemes – AIER". www.aier.org. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  69. "Japan Releases Stimulus Package as Recovery Weakens (Update3)". Bloomberg News. 16 August 2023.
  70. "Japan inflation rate hits 23-year high". BBC News. 2014-05-30. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  71. "Abe unveils 'massive' coronavirus stimulus worth 20% of GDP". The Japan Times. 2020-04-06. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  72. Kihara, Kaori Kaneko, Leika (2020-12-18). "Japan's consumer prices fall at fastest pace in decade, stoke deflation fears". Reuters. Retrieved 2021-02-04.{{cite news}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  73. "Deflation fears reignited as pandemic hits consumer prices in Japan". The Japan Times. 2020-05-01. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  74. FocusEconomics. "Japan Inflation Rate (CPI) - Japan Economy Forecast & Outlook". FocusEconomics | Economic Forecasts from the World's Leading Economists. Retrieved 2021-02-04.
  75. Bank of England Quarterly inflation report Feb 2009 p. 33 chart A
  76. ^ Atack, Jeremy; Passell, Peter (1994). A New Economic View of American History. New York: W.W. Norton and Co. p. 102. ISBN 0-393-96315-2.
  77. "Inflation, ho! (a primer on deflation)". Grant's Interest Rate Observer. 23 May 2003. Archived from the original on 28 February 2006.
  78. Wells, David A. (1890). Recent Economic Changes and Their Effect on Production and Distribution of Wealth and Well-Being of Society. New York: D. Appleton and Co. ISBN 0-543-72474-3.
  79. Rothbard, Murray (2002). History of Money and Banking in the United States. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. pp. 164–8. ISBN 0-945466-33-1.
  80. Rosenberg, Yuval (26 February 2015). "America Is In Deflation. So What?". The Fiscal Times.
  81. "FOMC statement" (Press release). Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 16 December 2008.
  82. Roubini, Nouriel (30 October 2008). "Get Ready For 'Stag-Deflation'". Forbes.
  83. Svaldi, Aldo (13 October 2009). "Colorado minimum wage set to fall". The Denver Post.

References

  • Nicola Acocella, The deflationary bias of exit strategies in the EMU countries, in: Review of economic conditions in Italy, 2-3: 471–93, (2011).
  • Ben S. Bernanke. Deflation: Making Sure "It" Doesn't Happen Here. USA Federal Reserve Board. 2002-11-21. Accessed: 2008-10-17. (Archived by WebCite at https://web.archive.org/web/20081024060408/http://www.federalreserve.gov/BOARDDOCS/SPEECHES/2002/20021121/default.htm
  • Michael Bordo & Andrew Filardo, Deflation and monetary policy in a historical perspective: Remembering the past or being condemned to repeat it?, In: Economic Policy, October 2005, pp. 799–844.
  • Georg Erber, The Risk of Deflation in Germany and the Monetary Policy of the ECB. In: Cesifo Forum 4 (2003), 3, pp. 24–29
  • Charles Goodhart and Boris Hofmann, Deflation, credit and asset prices, In: Deflation - Current and Historical Perspectives, eds. Richard C. K. Burdekin & Pierre L. Siklos, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2004.
  • International Monetary Fund, Deflation: Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options - Findings of an Independent Task Force, Washington D. C., April 30, 2003.
  • International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook 2006 – Globalization and Inflation, Washington D. C., April 2006.
  • Otmar Issing, The euro after four years: is there a risk of deflation?, 16th European Finance Convention, 2 December 2002, London, Europäische Zentralbank, Frankfurt am Main
  • Steven B. Kamin, Mario Marazzi & John W. Schindler, Is China "Exporting Deflation"?, International Finance Discussion Papers No. 791, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington D. C. January 2004.
  • Krugman, Paul (1998). "Its Baaaaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap" (PDF). Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1998 (2): 137–205. doi:10.2307/2534694. JSTOR 2534694. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2016-12-03.

External links

Economics
Theoretical
Empirical
Applied
Schools
(history)
Economists
Lists
Economic expansions and recessions in the United States and Commonwealth of Nations countries
Commercial revolution
(1000–1760)
1st Industrial Revolution
(1760–1840)
Early Victorian Britain/
Civil War-era United States
(1840–1870)
Gilded Age/
2nd Industrial Revolution
(1870–1914)
Interwar period
(1918–1939)
Post–WWII expansion
(1945–1973)
Great Inflation
(1973–1982)
Great Moderation/
Great Regression
(1982–2007)
Information Age
(2007–present)
Categories: