This is an old revision of this page, as edited by Bongomatic (talk | contribs) at 02:37, 20 March 2009 (Added {{notability}} and {{unreferenced}} tags to article. using Friendly). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.
Revision as of 02:37, 20 March 2009 by Bongomatic (talk | contribs) (Added {{notability}} and {{unreferenced}} tags to article. using Friendly)(diff) ← Previous revision | Latest revision (diff) | Newer revision → (diff)The topic of this article may not meet Misplaced Pages's general notability guideline. Please help to demonstrate the notability of the topic by citing reliable secondary sources that are independent of the topic and provide significant coverage of it beyond a mere trivial mention. If notability cannot be shown, the article is likely to be merged, redirected, or deleted. Find sources: "Non-imposition" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (March 2009) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
This article does not cite any sources. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. Find sources: "Non-imposition" – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (March 2009) (Learn how and when to remove this message) |
In social choice theory, non-imposition is the property of a voting system that states that no choice will be imposed on the participants which is irrespective of their choices. This is one of the criteria for Arrow's Impossibility Theorem.
Categories: