Misplaced Pages

Capitalism: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively
← Previous editContent deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 12:50, 23 November 2017 editDalliance (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users, Pending changes reviewers9,265 edits Reverted 1 pending edit by Han Su to revision 811713093 by Favonian← Previous edit Latest revision as of 07:41, 11 January 2025 edit undoEarthDude (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users1,671 edits Further reading: Added a book to further readingTags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit Advanced mobile edit 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Economic system based on private ownership}}
{{pp-pc}}
{{About|an economic system}}
{{Pp-move-indef|small=yes}}
{{Redirect|Capitalist|other uses|Capitalist (disambiguation)}}
{{About|the economic system}}
{{Pp-pc|small=yes}}
{{Redirect2|Capitalist|Free enterprise|the racehorse|Capitalist (horse)|other uses|Free enterprise (disambiguation)}}{{Use American English|date=January 2014}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=November 2017}} {{Use American English|date=January 2014}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=June 2020}}
{{Capitalism |expanded=all}}
{{Economic systems sidebar|expanded=By ideology}} {{Capitalism sidebar}}
{{Economics sidebar}}
'''Capitalism''' is an ] and an ] based on ] of the ] and their operation for ].<ref>{{cite book|last=Zimbalist, Sherman and Brown|first= Andrew, Howard J. and Stuart|title= Comparing Economic Systems: A Political-Economic Approach|publisher=Harcourt College Pub|date=October 1988|isbn= 978-0-15-512403-5|pages=6–7|quote=Pure capitalism is defined as a system wherein all of the means of production (physical capital) are privately owned and run by the capitalist class for a profit, while most other people are workers who work for a salary or wage (and who do not own the capital or the product).}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|last1=Rosser|first1=Mariana V.|last2=Rosser|first2=J Barkley|title=Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy|publisher=MIT Press|date=23 July 2003|isbn=978-0-262-18234-8|page=7|quote=In capitalist economies, land and produced means of production (the capital stock) are owned by private individuals or groups of private individuals organized as firms.}}</ref><ref>Chris Jenks. ''Core Sociological Dichotomies''. "Capitalism, as a mode of production, is an economic system of manufacture and exchange which is geared toward the production and sale of commodities within a market for profit, where the manufacture of commodities consists of the use of the formally free labor of workers in exchange for a wage to create commodities in which the manufacturer extracts surplus value from the labor of the workers in terms of the difference between the wages paid to the worker and the value of the commodity produced by him/her to generate that profit." London, England, UK; Thousand Oaks, California, US; New Delhi, India. SAGE. p. 383.</ref> Characteristics central to capitalism include ], ], ], ], a ] and ].<ref>Heilbroner, Robert L. . Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume, eds. ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics''. 2nd {{abbr|ed.|edition}} (Palgrave Macmillan, 2008) {{DOI|10.1057/9780230226203.0198}}</ref><ref>Louis Hyman and Edward E. Baptist (2014). ''.'' ]. {{ISBN|978-1-4767-8431-1}}.</ref> In a capitalist ], decision-making and investment are determined by the owners of the factors of production in ] and ]s, whereas prices and the distribution of goods are mainly determined by competition in the market.<ref>{{cite book|last=Gregory and Stuart|first=Paul and Robert|title=The Global Economy and its Economic Systems|publisher= South-Western College Pub|date=28 February 2013|isbn=978-1-285-05535-0|page=41|quote=Capitalism is characterized by private ownership of the factors of production. Decision making is decentralized and rests with the owners of the factors of production. Their decision making is coordinated by the market, which provides the necessary information. Material incentives are used to motivate participants.}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/capitalism|title=Definition of CAPITALISM|publisher=}}</ref>
{{Economic systems sidebar|expanded=by ideology}}
{{Liberalism sidebar}}
{{Neoliberalism sidebar}}


'''Capitalism''' is an ] based on the ] of the ] and their operation for ].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Zimbalist |last2=Sherman |last3=Brown |first1=Andrew |first2=Howard J. |first3=Stuart |title=Comparing Economic Systems: A Political-Economic Approach |publisher=] |date=October 1988 |isbn=978-0-15-512403-5 |pages= |quote=Pure capitalism is defined as a system wherein all of the means of production (physical capital) are privately owned and run by the capitalist class for a profit, while most other people are workers who work for a salary or wage (and who do not own the capital or the product). |url=https://archive.org/details/comparingeconomi0000zimb_q8i6/page/6}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Rosser |first1=Mariana V. |last2=Rosser |first2=J Barkley |title=Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy |publisher=] |date=23 July 2003 |isbn=978-0-262-18234-8 |page=7 |quote=In capitalist economies, land and produced means of production (the capital stock) are owned by private individuals or groups of private individuals organized as firms.}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |first=Chris |last=Jenks |title=Core Sociological Dichotomies |quote=Capitalism, as a mode of production, is an economic system of manufacture and exchange which is geared toward the production and sale of commodities within a market for profit, where the manufacture of commodities consists of the use of the formally free labor of workers in exchange for a wage to create commodities in which the manufacturer extracts surplus value from the labor of the workers in terms of the difference between the wages paid to the worker and the value of the commodity produced by him/her to generate that profit. |location=London; Thousand Oaks, CA; New Delhi |publisher=] |page=383}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |title=The Challenge of Global Capitalism : The World Economy in the 21st Century |last=Gilpin |first=Robert |author-link=Robert Gilpin |isbn=978-0-691-18647-4 |oclc=1076397003 |date=2018|publisher=Princeton University Press }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Sternberg |first1=Elaine |title=Defining Capitalism |journal=] |date=2015 |volume=35 |issue=3 |pages=380–396 |doi=10.1111/ecaf.12141|s2cid=219373247 | issn = 0265-0665}}</ref> The defining characteristics of capitalism include ], ], ]s, ]s, recognition of ], ], ], ], ], ], ], a ] that makes possible ] and ], ], ], ], ], production of ] and ]s, and a strong emphasis on ] and ].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Heilbroner |first1=Robert L. |title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |date=2018 |publisher=] |location=London |isbn=978-1-349-95189-5 |pages=1378–1389 |chapter-url=https://link.springer.com/referenceworkentry/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_154 |language=en |chapter=Capitalism |doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_154}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Hodgson |first1=Geoffrey M. |title=Conceptualizing Capitalism: Institutions, Evolution, Future |date=2015 |publisher=] |location=Chicago |isbn=9780226168142 |url=https://press.uchicago.edu/ucp/books/book/chicago/C/bo18523749.html}}</ref><ref name = "harris">{{cite journal |last1=Harris |first1=Neal |last2=Delanty |first2=Gerard |title=What is capitalism? Toward a working definition |journal=] |date=2023 |volume=62 |issue=3 |pages=323–344 |doi=10.1177/05390184231203878 |doi-access=free}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Berend |first1=Ivan T. |title=Capitalism |journal=] |date=2015 |pages=94–98 |doi=10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.62003-2|isbn=978-0-08-097087-5 }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Antonio |first1=Robert J. |last2=Bonanno |first2=Alessandro |title=Capitalism |journal=The Wiley-Blackwell Encyclopedia of Globalization |date=2012 |doi=10.1002/9780470670590.wbeog060|isbn=978-1-4051-8824-1 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Beamish |first1=Rob |chapter=Capitalism |title=Core Concepts in Sociology |date=2018 |pages=17–22 |doi=10.1002/9781394260331.ch6|isbn=978-1-119-16861-4 }}</ref> In a ], decision-making and investments are determined by owners of wealth, property, or ability to maneuver capital or production ability in ] and ]s—whereas prices and the distribution of goods and services are mainly determined by competition in goods and services markets.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Gregory |first1=Paul |last2=Stuart |first2=Robert |year=2013 |title=The Global Economy and its Economic Systems |publisher=] |page=41 |isbn=978-1-285-05535-0 |quote=Capitalism is characterized by private ownership of the factors of production. Decision making is decentralized and rests with the owners of the factors of production. Their decision making is coordinated by the market, which provides the necessary information. Material incentives are used to motivate participants.}}</ref>
]s, ], ]s, and ]s have adopted different perspectives in their analyses of capitalism and have recognized various forms of it in practice. These include '']'' or ] capitalism, ] and ]. Different forms of capitalism feature varying degrees of free markets, public ownership,<ref>{{cite book|last=Gregory and Stuart|first=Paul and Robert|title=The Global Economy and its Economic Systems|publisher=South-Western College Pub|date=28 February 2013|isbn=978-1-285-05535-0|page=107|quote=Real-world capitalist systems are mixed, some having higher shares of public ownership than others. The mix changes when privatization or nationalization occurs. Privatization is when property that had been state-owned is transferred to private owners. Nationalization occurs when privately owned property becomes publicly owned.}}</ref> obstacles to free competition and state-sanctioned ]. The degree of ] in markets, the role of ] and regulation and the scope of state ownership vary across different <span class="plainlinks">.</span><ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54">''Macmillan Dictionary of Modern Economics'', 3rd Ed., 1986, p. 54.</ref> The extent to which different markets are free, as well as the rules defining private property, are matters of politics and ]. Most existing capitalist economies are ], which combine elements of free markets with state intervention and in some cases ].<ref name="Stilwell">Stilwell, Frank. “Political Economy: the Contest of Economic Ideas.” First Edition. Oxford University Press. Melbourne, Australia. 2002.</ref>


Economists, historians, political economists, and sociologists have adopted different perspectives in their analyses of capitalism and have recognized various forms of it in practice. These include '']'' or ], ], ], and ]. Different ] feature varying degrees of ]s, ],<ref name="gregorystuart">{{cite book|last1=Gregory |first1=Paul |last2=Stuart |first2=Robert |title=The Global Economy and its Economic Systems |publisher=] |date=2013 |isbn=978-1-285-05535-0 |page=107 |quote=Real-world capitalist systems are mixed, some having higher shares of public ownership than others. The mix changes when privatization or nationalization occurs. Privatization is when property that had been state-owned is transferred to private owners. ] occurs when privately owned property becomes publicly owned.}}</ref> obstacles to free competition, and state-sanctioned ]. The degree of ] in ] and the role of ] and ], as well as the scope of state ownership, vary across different models of capitalism.<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54">{{cite book |title=Macmillan Dictionary of Modern Economics |edition=3rd |date=1986 |pages=54}}</ref><ref>{{cite magazine |last=Bronk |first=Richard |title=Which model of capitalism?|url=http://oecdobserver.org/news/archivestory.php/aid/345/Which_model_of_capitalism_.html |url-status=live |magazine=] |publisher=] |date=Summer 2000 |volume=1999 |issue=221–222 |pages=12–15 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180406200423/http://oecdobserver.org/news/archivestory.php/aid/345/Which_model_of_capitalism_.html |archive-date=6 April 2018 |access-date=6 April 2018}}</ref> The extent to which different markets are free and the rules defining private property are matters of politics and policy. Most of the existing capitalist economies are ] that combine elements of free markets with state intervention and in some cases ].<ref name="Stilwell">{{cite book |last=Stilwell |first=Frank |author-link=Frank Stilwell (economist) |title=Political Economy: the Contest of Economic Ideas |edition=1st |publisher=] |location=Melbourne, Australia |date=2002}}</ref>
] have existed under many ], in many different times, places and cultures. However, the development of capitalist societies marked by a universalization of ]-based social relations, a consistently large and system-wide ] and a capitalist class which dominates control of wealth and political power developed in ] in a process that led to the ]. ] have since become dominant in the ] and continue to spread.


Capitalism in its modern form emerged from ] in ], as well as ] practices by European countries between the 16th and 18th centuries. The Industrial Revolution of the 18th century established ], characterized by ], and a complex ]. Through the process of ], capitalism spread across the world in the 19th and 20th centuries, especially before World War I and after the end of the Cold War. During the 19th century, capitalism was largely unregulated by the state, but became more regulated in the post–] period through ], followed by a return of more unregulated capitalism starting in the 1980s through ].
Capitalism has been criticized for establishing power in the hands of a minority capitalist class that exists through the exploitation of a working class majority; for prioritizing profit over social good, natural resources and the environment; and for being an engine of inequality and economic instabilities. Supporters argue that it provides better products through competition, creates strong economic growth, yields productivity and prosperity that greatly benefits society, as well as being the most efficient system known for allocation of resources.

The existence of market economies has been observed under many ] and across a vast array of ], ]s, and cultural contexts. The modern industrial capitalist societies that exist today developed in Western Europe as a result of the Industrial Revolution. The accumulation of capital is the primary mechanism through which capitalist economies promote ]. However, it is a characteristic of such economies that they experience a ] of ] followed by recessions.<ref name = "HP">{{cite journal |last1=Hodrick |first1=R. |last2=Prescott|first2= E. |year=1997 |title=Postwar US business cycles: An empirical investigation |journal=Journal of Money, Credit and Banking|volume=29|issue=1 |pages=1–16|doi=10.2307/2953682 |jstor=2953682 |s2cid=154995815 | url = http://www.kellogg.northwestern.edu/research/math/papers/451.pdf}}</ref>


== Etymology == == Etymology ==
{|class="box" style="float: right; margin-left: 1em; text-align: left; border: 4px solid #aaa; padding: 2px; font-size: 100%; width: 30%;"
|-
|style="background:#dbeaff;"|Other terms sometimes used for capitalism:
* ]<ref>{{cite book|last=Mandel|first=Ernst|authorlink=Ernst Mandel|title=An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C&pg=PA24|accessdate=29 January 2017|year=2002|publisher=Resistance Books|isbn=978-1-876646-30-1|page=24}}</ref>
* ]<ref>{{cite journal |title=Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism|author=Werhane, P. H.|journal=The Review of Metaphysics|volume=47|year=1994|publisher=Philosophy Education Society|issue=3}}</ref>
* Free enterprise<ref name="rogetfreeenterprise">"Free enterprise". Roget's 21st Century Thesaurus, Third Edition. Philip Lief Group 2008.</ref>
* Free enterprise economy<ref name="britannica"/>
* ]<ref name="rogetfreeenterprise"/><ref name="mutualist">. "...&nbsp;based on voluntary cooperation, free exchange, or mutual aid."</ref>
* Free market economy<ref name="britannica"/>
* '']''<ref name=Barrons>Barrons Dictionary of Finance and Investment Terms, 1995; p. 74.</ref>
* ] <ref>, Merriam-Webster Unabridged Dictionary</ref>
* ] <ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.cato.org/about.php |title=About Cato |publisher=Cato Institute • www.cato.org |accessdate=6 November 2008}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.cato.org/university/module10.html |title=The Achievements of Nineteenth-Century Classical Liberalism |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20090211160820/http://www.cato.org/university/module10.html |archivedate=11 February 2009 }} {{quote|Although the term "liberalism" retains its original meaning in most of the world, it has unfortunately come to have a very different meaning in late twentieth-century America. Hence terms such as "market liberalism," "classical liberalism," or "libertarianism" are often used in its place in America.}}</ref>
* ]<ref name="Duménil" />
* Self-regulating market <ref name="rogetfreeenterprise" />
* Profits system<ref>{{cite book |last= Shutt|first= Harry|title= Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for the Post-Capitalist Era |publisher= Zed Books|year= 2010|isbn= 1-84813-417-7}}</ref>
|}
The term "capitalist", meaning an owner of ], appears earlier than the term "capitalism" and it dates back to the mid-17th century. "Capitalism" is derived from ''capital'', which evolved from ''capitale'', a late ] word based on ''caput'', meaning "head"{{snd}}also the origin of '']'' and '']'' in the sense of movable property (only much later to refer only to livestock). ''Capitale'' emerged in the 12th to 13th centuries in the sense of referring to funds, stock of merchandise, sum of money or money carrying interest.<ref name="Braudel on capitalism232">Braudel p. 232</ref><ref>{{OEtymD|cattle}}</ref><ref name="OED-93">James Augustus Henry Murray. "Capital". . ''Oxford English Press''. {{abbr|Vol.|Volume}} 2. p. 93.</ref> By 1283, it was used in the sense of the capital assets of a trading firm and it was frequently interchanged with a number of other words{{snd}}wealth, money, funds, goods, assets, property and so on.<ref name="Braudel on capitalism233">Braudel p. 233</ref>


The term "capitalist", meaning an owner of ], appears earlier than the term "capitalism" and dates to the mid-17th century. "Capitalism" is derived from ''capital'', which evolved from {{lang|la|capitale}}, a late ] word based on {{lang|la|caput}}, meaning "head"—which is also the origin of "]" and "]" in the sense of movable property (only much later to refer only to livestock). {{lang|la|Capitale}} emerged in the 12th to 13th centuries to refer to funds, stock of merchandise, sum of money or money carrying interest.<ref name="Braudel-1979">{{cite book |last=Braudel |first=Fernand |author-link=Fernand Braudel |title=The Wheels of Commerce: Civilization and Capitalism 15th–18th Century |publisher=] |date=1979}}</ref>{{rp|232}}<ref name="OED-93">]. "Capital". . ''Oxford English Press''. {{abbr|Vol.|Volume}} 2. p. 93.</ref> By 1283, it was used in the sense of the capital assets of a trading firm and was often interchanged with other words—wealth, money, funds, goods, assets, property and so on.<ref name="Braudel-1979" />{{rp|233}}
The ''Hollandische Mercurius'' uses ''capitalists'' in 1633 and 1654 to refer to owners of capital.<ref name="Braudel on capitalism234">Braudel p. 234</ref> In French, ] referred to ''capitalistes'' in 1788,<ref>E.g., "L'Angleterre a-t-elle l'heureux privilège de n'avoir ni Agioteurs, ni Banquiers, ni Faiseurs de services, ni Capitalistes ?" in (1788) ''De la foi publique envers les créanciers de l'état : lettres à M. Linguet sur le n° CXVI de ses annales'' </ref> six years before its first recorded English usage by ] in his work ''Travels in France'' (1792).<ref name="OED-93" /><ref>Arthur Young. .</ref> In his '']'' (1817), ] referred to "the capitalist" many times.<ref>Ricardo, David. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. 1821. John Murray Publisher, 3rd edition.</ref> ], an English poet, used "capitalist" in his work ''Table Talk'' (1823).<ref>Samuel Taylor Coleridge. . p. 267.</ref> ] used the term "capitalist" in his first work, '']'' (1840), to refer to the owners of capital. ] used the term "capitalist" in his 1845 work '']''.<ref name="OED-93" />


The ''Hollantse ({{langx|de|holländische}}) Mercurius'' uses "capitalists" in 1633 and 1654 to refer to owners of capital.<ref name="Braudel-1979" />{{rp|234}} In French, ] referred to ''capitalistes'' in 1788,<ref>E.g., "L'Angleterre a-t-elle l'heureux privilège de n'avoir ni Agioteurs, ni Banquiers, ni Faiseurs de services, ni Capitalistes ?" in (1788) ''De la foi publique envers les créanciers de l'état : lettres à M. Linguet sur le n° CXVI de ses annales'' {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150319071130/http://books.google.com/books?id=ESMVAAAAQAAJ&pg=PA19 |date=19 March 2015 }}</ref> four years before its first recorded English usage by ] in his work ''Travels in France'' (1792).<ref name="OED-93" /><ref>Arthur Young. .</ref> In his '']'' (1817), ] referred to "the capitalist" many times.<ref>Ricardo, David. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. 1821. John Murray Publisher, 3rd edition.</ref> English poet ] used "capitalist" in his work ''Table Talk'' (1823).<ref>Samuel Taylor Coleridge. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200223123202/https://books.google.com/books?id=ma-4W-XiGkIC |date=23 February 2020 }}. p. 267.</ref> ] used the term in his first work, '']'' (1840), to refer to the owners of capital. ] used the term in his 1845 work '']''.<ref name="OED-93" /> ] used "capitalist" in his ] presented to the United States Congress in 1791.
The initial usage of the term "capitalism" in its modern sense has been attributed to ] in 1850 ("What I call 'capitalism' that is to say the appropriation of capital by some to the exclusion of others") and Pierre-Joseph Proudhon in 1861 ("Economic and social regime in which capital, the source of income, does not generally belong to those who make it work through their labour").<ref>Braudel, Fernand. ''The Wheels of Commerce: Civilization and Capitalism 15th–18th Century'', Harper and Row, 1979, p. 237.</ref> ] and ] referred to the "capitalistic system"<ref>Karl Marx. Chapter 16: "Absolute and Relative Surplus-Value." '']'': "The prolongation of the working-day beyond the point at which the laborer would have produced just an equivalent for the value of his labor-power, and the appropriation of that surplus-labor by capital, this is production of absolute surplus-value. It forms the general groundwork of the ''capitalist system'', and the starting-point for the production of relative surplus-value."</ref><ref>Karl Marx. Chapter Twenty-Five: "The General Law of Capitalist Accumulation". ''Das Kapital''.</ref> and to the "capitalist mode of production" in '']'' (1867).<ref>Saunders, Peter (1995). ''Capitalism''. University of Minnesota Press. P. 1.</ref> The use of the word "capitalism" in reference to an economic system appears twice in Volume I of ''The Capital'', p.&nbsp;124 (German edition) and in ''Theories of Surplus Value'', tome II, p.&nbsp;493 (German edition). Marx did not extensively use the form capitalism, but instead those of capitalist and capitalist mode of production'','' which appear more than 2,600 times in the trilogy The ''Capital.'' According to the '']'' (OED), the term "capitalism" first appeared in English in 1854 in the novel '']'' by novelist ], where he meant "having ownership of capital".<ref name="OED-94">James Augustus Henry Murray. "Capitalism" p. 94.</ref> Also according to the OED, ], a ] ] and ], used the phrase "private capitalism" in 1863.


The initial use of the term "capitalism" in its modern sense is attributed to ] in 1850 ("What I call 'capitalism' that is to say the appropriation of capital by some to the exclusion of others") and Pierre-Joseph Proudhon in 1861 ("Economic and social regime in which capital, the source of income, does not generally belong to those who make it work through their labor").<ref name="Braudel-1979" />{{rp|237}} ] frequently referred to the "]" and to the "capitalist mode of production" in '']'' (1867).<ref>{{cite book |last=Saunders |first=Peter |date=1995 |title=Capitalism |publisher=] |page=1}}</ref><ref name=":0">MEW, 23, & Das Kapital. Kritik der politischen Oekonomie. Erster Band-Verlag von Otto Meissner (1867)</ref> Marx did not use the form ''capitalism'' but instead used ], ''capitalist'' and ''capitalist mode of production'', which appear frequently.<ref name=":0" /><ref>The use of the word "capitalism" appears in ''Theories of Surplus Value'', volume II. ToSV was edited by Kautsky.</ref> Due to the word being coined by socialist critics of capitalism, economist and historian ] stated that the term "capitalism" itself is a term of disparagement and a misnomer for ].<ref>Hessen, Robert (2008) "Capitalism", in Henderson, David R. (ed.) ''The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics'' p. 57</ref> ] agrees with the statement that the term is a misnomer, adding that it misleadingly suggests that there is such a thing as "]" that inherently functions in certain ways and is governed by stable economic laws of its own.<ref>Harcourt, Bernard E. (2020) ''For Coöperation and the Abolition of Capital, Or, How to Get Beyond Our Extractive Punitive Society and Achieve a Just Society'', Rochester, NY: Columbia Public Law Research Paper No. 14-672, p. 31</ref>
== History ==
{{Main article|History of capitalism}}
] has existed incipiently on a small scale for centuries,<ref name="WarburtonDavid">Warburton, David. ''Macroeconomics from the beginning: The General Theory, Ancient Markets, and the Rate of Interest''. Paris, Recherches et Publications, 2003. p. 49.</ref> in the form of merchant, renting and lending activities, and occasionally as small-scale industry with some wage labour. Simple ] exchange, and consequently simple commodity production, which are the initial basis for the growth of capital from trade, have a very long history. The "capitalistic era" according to Karl Marx dates from 16th century merchants and small urban workshops.<ref name=GSGB>{{cite web|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C|title=An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory|date=1 January 2002|publisher=Resistance Books|via=Google Books}}</ref> Marx knew that wage labour existed on a modest scale for centuries before capitalist industry. Early Islam promulgated capitalist economic policies, which migrated to Europe through trade partners from cities such as Venice.<ref name="Koehler, Benedikt">Koehler, Benedikt. ''Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism'' (Lexington Books, 2014).</ref> Capitalism in its modern form can be traced to the emergence of agrarian capitalism and mercantilism in the ].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.economist.com/node/13484709|title=Cradle of capitalism|publisher=|via=The Economist}}</ref>


In the ], the term "capitalism" first appears, according to the '']'' (OED), in 1854, in the novel '']'' by novelist ], where the word meant "having ownership of capital".<ref name="OED-94">]. "Capitalism" p. 94.</ref> Also according to the OED, ], a ] ] and ], used the term "private capitalism" in 1863.
Thus for much of history, capital and commercial trade existed, but it did not lead to industrialisation or dominate the production process of society. That required a set of conditions, including specific technologies of mass production, the ability to independently and privately own and trade in means of production, a class of workers willing to sell their ] for a living, a ] framework promoting commerce, a physical infrastructure allowing the circulation of goods on a large scale, and security for private accumulation. Many of these conditions do not currently exist in many ] countries, although there is plenty of capital and labour. Thus, the obstacles for the development of capitalist markets are less technical and more social, cultural and political.


=== Agrarian capitalism === Other terms sometimes used for capitalism are:
* ]<ref>{{cite book |last=Mandel |first=Ernst |author-link=Ernst Mandel |title=An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C&pg=PA24 |year=2002 |publisher=] |isbn=978-1-876646-30-1 |page=24 |access-date=29 January 2017 |archive-date=15 February 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170215160137/https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C&pg=PA24 |url-status=live}}</ref>
The economic foundations of the feudal agricultural system began to shift substantially in 16th-century England; the ] had broken down, and land began to become concentrated in the hands of fewer landlords with increasingly large estates. Instead of a ]-based system of labor, workers were increasingly employed as part of a broader and expanding money-based economy. The system put pressure on both landlords and tenants to increase the productivity of agriculture to make profit; the weakened coercive power of the ] to extract peasant ] encouraged them to try better methods, and the tenants also had incentive to improve their methods, in order to flourish in a competitive ]. Terms of rent for land were becoming subject to economic market forces rather than to the previous stagnant system of custom and feudal obligation.<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Brenner|first1=Robert|title=The Agrarian Roots of European Capitalism|journal=Past & Present|date=1 January 1982|issue=97|pages=16–113|jstor=650630}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url= http://monthlyreview.org/1998/07/01/the-agrarian-origins-of-capitalism|title= The Agrarian Origins of Capitalism|accessdate= 17 December 2012}}</ref>
* ]<ref>{{cite journal |title=Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism |last=Werhane |first=P. H. |journal=The Review of Metaphysics |volume=47 |year=1994 |issue=3}}</ref>
* Free enterprise<ref name="rogetfreeenterprise">{{cite encyclopedia |title=Free enterprise |encyclopedia=Roget's 21st Century Thesaurus |edition=Third |publisher=Philip Lief Group |date=2008}}</ref>{{page needed|date=July 2021}}
* Free enterprise economy<ref name="britannica" />
* ]<ref name="rogetfreeenterprise" />{{page needed|date=July 2021}}
* Free market economy<ref name="britannica" />
* '']''<ref name=Barrons>{{cite book |title=Barrons Dictionary of Finance and Investment Terms |date=1995 |page=74}}</ref>
* ]<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |url=https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/market%20economy |title=Market economy |dictionary=Merriam-Webster Unabridged Dictionary}}</ref>
* Profits system<ref>{{cite book |last=Shutt |first=Harry |title=Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for the Post-Capitalist Era |publisher=] |year=2010 |isbn=978-1-84813-417-1}}</ref>{{page needed|date=July 2021}}
* Self-regulating market<ref name="rogetfreeenterprise" />{{page needed|date=July 2021}}


== Definition ==
By the early 17th-century, England was a centralized state in which much of the feudal order of ] had been swept away. This centralization was strengthened by a good system of roads and by a disproportionately large capital city, ]. The capital acted as a central market hub for the entire country, creating a very large internal market for goods, contrasting with the fragmented feudal holdings that prevailed in most parts of the ].
There is no universally agreed upon definition of capitalism; it is unclear whether or not capitalism characterizes an entire society, a specific type of social order, or crucial
components or elements of a society.<ref name="wolf">{{cite encyclopedia |last=Wolf |first=Harald |editor1-last=Ritzer |editor1-first=George|title=Capitalism |encyclopedia=Encyclopedia of Social Theory|pages=76–80|date=2004 |publisher=Sage Publications|isbn=978-1-4522-6546-9}}</ref> Societies officially founded in opposition to capitalism (such as the ]) have sometimes been argued to actually exhibit characteristics of capitalism.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Howard |first1=M.C. |last2=King |first2=J.E. |title='State Capitalism' in the Soviet Union |journal=History of Economics Review |date=January 2001 |volume=34 |issue=1 |pages=110–126 |doi=10.1080/10370196.2001.11733360 |s2cid=42809979 |url=https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/pdf/10.1080/10370196.2001.11733360 |language=en |issn=1037-0196}}</ref> ] describes usage of the term "capitalism" by many authors as "mainly rhetorical, functioning less as an actual concept than as a gesture toward the
need for a concept".<ref name="harris"/> Scholars who are uncritical of capitalism rarely actually use the term "capitalism".<ref name="delacroix">{{cite encyclopedia |last=Delacroix |first=Jacques |editor1-last=Ritzer |editor1-first=George |title=Capitalism |encyclopedia=Encyclopedia of Social Theory|date=2007 |publisher=Wiley|doi=10.1002/9781405165518.wbeosc004 |isbn=978-1-4051-2433-1|url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/9781405165518.wbeosc004}}</ref>
Some doubt that the term "capitalism" possesses valid scientific dignity,<ref name="wolf"/> and it is generally not discussed in ],<ref name="harris"/> with economist ] suggesting that the term "capitalism" should be abandoned entirely.<ref>{{cite book |last=Acemoglu |first=Daron |date=2017 |editor1-last=Frey |editor1-first=Bruno S.|editor2-last = Iselin|editor2-first = David |title=Economic Ideas You Should Forget |publisher=Springer|pages=1–3 |chapter=Capitalism|doi=10.1007/978-3-319-47458-8_1 |isbn=978-3-319-47457-1|chapter-url=https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-3-319-47458-8_1}}</ref> Consequently, understanding of the concept of capitalism tends to be heavily influenced by opponents of capitalism and by the followers and critics of Karl Marx.<ref name="delacroix"/>


=== Mercantilism === == History ==
{{Main article|Mercantilism}} {{Main|History of capitalism}}
] (pictured in a 16th-century portrait by ]) built an international financial empire and was one of the first ]ers.]]
]]]
], the centre of early capitalism<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |last1=Behringer |first1=Wolfgang |contribution=Core and Periphery: The Holy Roman Empire as a Communication(s) Universe |title=The Holy Roman Empire, 1495–1806 |date=2011 |publisher=Oxford University Press |location=Oxford |isbn=978-0-19-960297-1 |pages=347–358|url=https://perspectivia.net/servlets/MCRFileNodeServlet/pnet_derivate_00004689/behringer_core.pdf |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221009/https://perspectivia.net/servlets/MCRFileNodeServlet/pnet_derivate_00004689/behringer_core.pdf |archive-date=9 October 2022 |url-status=live |access-date=7 August 2022}}</ref>]]
The economic doctrine prevailing from the 16th to the 18th centuries is commonly called ].<ref name=GSGB /><ref name="Burnham">{{cite book |author=Burnham, Peter|title=Capitalism: The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics|publisher=Oxford University Press|year=2003}}</ref> This period, the ], was associated with the geographic exploration of the foreign lands by merchant traders, especially from England and the ]. Mercantilism was a system of trade for profit, although commodities were still largely produced by non-capitalist methods.<ref name="Scott" /> Most scholars consider the era of merchant capitalism and mercantilism as the origin of modern capitalism,<ref name="Burnham 2003">Burnham (2003)</ref><ref name="Encyclopædia Britannica 2006">''Encyclopædia Britannica'' (2006)</ref> although ] argued that the hallmark of capitalism is the establishment of generalized markets for what he called the "fictitious commodities:" land, labor, and money. Accordingly, he argued that "not until 1834 was a competitive labor market established in England, hence industrial capitalism as a social system cannot be said to have existed before that date.''<ref>Polanyi, Karl. ''The Great Transformation.'' Beacon Press, Boston. 1944. p. 87.</ref>


Capitalism, in its modern form, can be traced to the emergence of agrarian capitalism and mercantilism in the early ], in city-states like ].<ref>{{cite news |url=http://www.economist.com/node/13484709 |title=Cradle of capitalism |newspaper=] |date=16 April 2009 |access-date=9 March 2015 |archive-date=18 January 2018 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180118055643/http://www.economist.com/node/13484709 |url-status=live}}</ref> ] has existed incipiently on a small scale for centuries<ref name="WarburtonDavid">{{cite book |last=Warburton |first=David |title=Macroeconomics from the beginning: The General Theory, Ancient Markets, and the Rate of Interest |location=Paris |publisher=Recherches et Publications |date=2003 |pages=49}}</ref> in the form of merchant, renting and lending activities and occasionally as small-scale industry with some wage labor. Simple ] exchange and consequently simple commodity production, which is the initial basis for the growth of capital from trade, have a very long history. During the ], ] promulgated capitalist economic policies such as free trade and banking. Their use of ] facilitated ]. These innovations migrated to Europe through trade partners in cities such as Venice and Pisa. Italian ] traveled the Mediterranean talking to Arab traders and returned to popularize the use of Indo-Arabic numerals in Europe.<ref name="Koehler, Benedikt">{{cite book |last=Koehler |first=Benedikt |title=Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism |quote=In Baghdad, by the early tenth century a fully-fledged banking sector had come into being... |pages=2 |publisher=] |date=2014}}</ref>
] after the ], which began ] rule in India]]
England began a large-scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the ] (1558–1603). A systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through ]'s argument ''England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure.'' It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664.<ref>{{cite book |author1=David Onnekink|author2=Gijs Rommelse|title=Ideology and Foreign Policy in Early Modern Europe (1650–1750)|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=M1QdbzdTimsC&pg=PA257|year= 2011|publisher=Ashgate Publishing|page=257|isbn=9781409419143}}</ref>


=== Agrarianism ===
European ]s, backed by state controls, subsidies, and ], made most of their profits by buying and selling goods. In the words of ], the purpose of mercantilism was "the opening and well-balancing of trade; the cherishing of manufacturers; the banishing of idleness; the repressing of waste and excess by sumptuary laws; the improvement and husbanding of the soil; the regulation of prices&nbsp;..."<ref>Quoted in Sir George Clark, ''The Seventeenth Century'' (New York, Oxford University Press, 1961), p. 24.</ref>
The economic foundations of the feudal agricultural system began to shift substantially in 16th-century England as the ] had broken down and land began to become concentrated in the hands of fewer landlords with increasingly large estates. Instead of a ]-based system of labor, workers were increasingly employed as part of a broader and expanding money-based economy. The system put pressure on both landlords and tenants to increase the productivity of agriculture to make profit; the weakened coercive power of the ] to extract peasant ] encouraged them to try better methods, and the tenants also had incentive to improve their methods in order to flourish in a competitive ]. Terms of rent for land were becoming subject to economic market forces rather than to the previous stagnant system of custom and feudal obligation.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Brenner |first1=Robert |title=The Agrarian Roots of European Capitalism |journal=] |date=1 January 1982 |issue=97 |pages=16–113 |doi=10.1093/past/97.1.16 |jstor=650630}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=http://monthlyreview.org/1998/07/01/the-agrarian-origins-of-capitalism |title=The Agrarian Origins of Capitalism |access-date=17 December 2012 |date=July 1998 |archive-date=11 December 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191211183143/https://monthlyreview.org/1998/07/01/the-agrarian-origins-of-capitalism/ |url-status=live}}</ref>


=== Mercantilism ===
The ] and the ] inaugurated an expansive era of commerce and trade.<ref name=Banaji>{{cite journal |author=Banaji, Jairus|year=2007|title=Islam, the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism|journal=Journal Historical Materialism|volume=15|pages=47–74|publisher=Brill Publishers|doi=10.1163/156920607X171591}}</ref><ref name="britannica2">{{cite book |title=Economic system:: Market systems|url=http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/178493/economic-system/61117/Market-systems#toc242146|publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica|year=2006}}</ref> These companies were characterized by their ] and ] powers given to them by nation-states.<ref name="Banaji" /> During this era, merchants, who had traded under the previous stage of mercantilism, invested capital in the East India Companies and other colonies, seeking a ].
{{Main|Mercantilism}}
]]]
] with the ] after the ] which began the British rule in ]]]
The economic doctrine prevailing from the 16th to the 18th centuries is commonly called ].<ref name=GSGB>{{cite book |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C |title=An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory |date= 2002 |publisher=] |via=] |isbn=978-1-876646-30-1 |access-date=27 August 2016 |archive-date=11 December 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161211173733/https://books.google.com/books?id=Pf9Jd1sIMJ0C |url-status=live}}</ref><ref name="Burnham">{{cite book |last=Burnham |first=Peter |author-link=Peter Burnham |title=Capitalism: The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics |publisher=] |year=2003}}</ref> This period, the ], was associated with the geographic exploration of foreign lands by merchant traders, especially from England and the ]. Mercantilism was a system of trade for profit, although commodities were still largely produced by non-capitalist methods.<ref name="Scott" /> Most scholars consider the era of merchant capitalism and mercantilism as the origin of modern capitalism,<ref name="Burnham"/><ref name="Encyclopædia Britannica 2006">''Encyclopædia Britannica'' (2006)</ref> although ] argued that the hallmark of capitalism is the establishment of generalized markets for what he called the "fictitious commodities", i.e. land, labor and money. Accordingly, he argued that "not until 1834 was a competitive labor market established in England, hence industrial capitalism as a social system cannot be said to have existed before that date".<ref>{{cite book |last=Polanyi |first=Karl |author-link=Karl Polanyi |title=The Great Transformation |publisher=] |location=Boston |date=1944 |pages=87}}</ref>


England began a large-scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the ] (1558–1603). A systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through ]'s argument ''England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure.'' It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664.<ref>{{cite book |first1=David |last1=Onnekink |first2=Gijs |last2=Rommelse |title=Ideology and Foreign Policy in Early Modern Europe (1650–1750) |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=M1QdbzdTimsC&pg=PA257 |year=2011 |publisher=] |page=257 |isbn=978-1-4094-1914-3 |access-date=27 June 2015 |archive-date=19 March 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150319130220/http://books.google.com/books?id=M1QdbzdTimsC&pg=PA257 |url-status=live}}</ref>
=== Industrial capitalism ===
]: the ] fuelled primarily by ] propelled the ] in ]<ref>Watt steam engine image: located in the lobby of into the Superior Technical School of Industrial Engineers of the UPM {{clarify|date=April 2016}} (])</ref>]]
In the mid-18th century, a new group of economic theorists, led by ]<ref>{{cite book |author=Hume, David|title=Political Discourses|location=Edinburgh|publisher=A. Kincaid & A. Donaldson|year=1752}}</ref> and ], challenged fundamental ] doctrines such as the belief that the world's wealth remained constant and that a state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state.


European ]s, backed by state controls, subsidies and ], made most of their profits by buying and selling goods. In the words of ], the purpose of mercantilism was "the opening and well-balancing of trade; the cherishing of manufacturers; the banishing of idleness; the repressing of waste and excess by sumptuary laws; the improvement and husbanding of the soil; the regulation of prices...".<ref>Quoted in {{cite book |first=George |last=Clark |title=The Seventeenth Century |location=New York |publisher=] |date=1961 |page=24}}</ref>
During the ], industrialists replaced merchants as a dominant factor in the capitalist system and affected the decline of the traditional handicraft skills of ]s, guilds, and ]. Also during this period, the surplus generated by the rise of commercial agriculture encouraged increased mechanization of agriculture. Industrial capitalism marked the development of the ] system of manufacturing, characterized by a complex ] between and within work process and the routine of work tasks; and finally established the global domination of the capitalist mode of production.<ref name="Burnham"/>


After the period of the ], the ] and the ], after massive contributions from the ],<ref name="Prakash">], "", ''History of World Trade Since 1450'', edited by ], vol. 1, Macmillan Reference USA, 2006, pp. 237–240, ''World History in Context''. Retrieved 3 August 2017</ref><ref name="ray">{{cite book |first=Indrajit |last=Ray |year=2011 |title=Bengal Industries and the British Industrial Revolution (1757–1857) |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=CHOrAgAAQBAJ&pg=PA57 |publisher=] |pages=57, 90, 174 |isbn=978-1-136-82552-1 |access-date=20 June 2019 |archive-date=29 May 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160529021839/https://books.google.com/books?id=CHOrAgAAQBAJ |url-status=live}}</ref> inaugurated an expansive era of commerce and trade.<ref name=Banaji>{{cite journal |last=Banaji |first=Jairus |year=2007 |title=Islam, the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism |journal=] |volume=15 |pages=47–74 |doi=10.1163/156920607X171591 |url=http://eprints.soas.ac.uk/15983/1/Islam%20and%20capitalism.pdf |access-date=20 April 2018 |archive-date=29 March 2018 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180329015002/http://eprints.soas.ac.uk/15983/1/Islam%20and%20capitalism.pdf |url-status=dead}}</ref><ref name="britannica2">{{cite book |title=Economic system:: Market systems |url=https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/178493/economic-system/61117/Market-systems#toc242146 |publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica |year=2006 |access-date=4 January 2009 |archive-date=24 May 2009 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090524075921/https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/178493/economic-system/61117/Market-systems#toc242146 |url-status=live}}</ref> These companies were characterized by their ] and ] powers given to them by nation-states.<ref name="Banaji" /> During this era, merchants, who had traded under the previous stage of mercantilism, invested capital in the East India Companies and other colonies, seeking a ].
Britain also abandoned its ] policy, as embraced by mercantilism. In the 19th century, ] and ], who based their beliefs on the ], initiated a movement to lower tariffs.<ref name="laissezf">{{cite web|title=laissez-faire |url=http://www.bartleby.com/65/la/laissezf.html |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20081202050426/http://www.bartleby.com/65/la/laissezf.html |archivedate=2 December 2008 |df=dmy }}</ref> In the 1840s, Britain adopted a less protectionist policy, with the repeal of the ] and the ].<ref name="Burnham"/> Britain reduced ] and ], in line with David Ricardo's advocacy for ].


=== Modern capitalism === === Industrial Revolution ===
{{Main|Industrial Revolution}}
{{Expand section|date=February 2017}}
], fuelled primarily by ], propelled the ] in ].<ref>Watt steam engine image located in the lobby of the Superior Technical School of Industrial Engineers of the ]{{clarify|date=April 2016}} (]).</ref>]]
] formed the financial basis of the international economy from 1870–1914]]
In the mid-18th century a group of economic theorists, led by ] (1711–1776)<ref>{{cite book |last=Hume |first=David |author-link=David Hume |title=Political Discourses |url=https://archive.org/details/McGillLibrary-125702-2590 |location=Edinburgh |publisher=A. Kincaid & A. Donaldson |year=1752}}</ref> and ] (1723–1790), challenged fundamental mercantilist doctrines—such as the belief that the world's wealth remained constant and that a state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state.
Capitalism was carried across the world by broader processes of ] and, by the end of the 18th century, became the dominant ''global'' economic system, in turn intensifying processes of economic and other globalization.<ref>{{Cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | authorlink= Paul James (academic) | last2= Gills | first2= Barry | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism | url= http://www.academia.edu/4199690/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol._1_Global_Markets_and_Capitalism_editor_with_Barry_Gills_Sage_Publications_London_2007 | publisher= Sage Publications | location= London}}</ref> Later, in the 20th century, capitalism overcame a challenge by ] and is now the encompassing system worldwide,<ref name="britannica">{{cite book |title=Capitalism|publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica|url=http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/93927/capitalism|date=10 November 2014}}</ref><ref>James Fulcher, ''Capitalism, A Very Short Introduction''. “In one respect there can, however, be little doubt that capitalism has gone global and that is in the elimination of alternative systems.” p. 99. Oxford University Press, 2004. {{ISBN|978-0-19-280218-7}}.</ref> with the ] being its dominant form in the industrialized Western world.


During the ], ] replaced merchants as a dominant factor in the capitalist system and effected the decline of the traditional handicraft skills of ]s, guilds and ]. Industrial capitalism marked the development of the ] of manufacturing, characterized by a complex ] between and within work process and the routine of work tasks; and eventually established the domination of the ].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Burnham |first1=Peter |author1-link=Peter Burnham |year=1996 |chapter=Capitalism |editor1-last=McLean |editor1-first=Iain |editor2-last=McMillan |editor2-first=Alistair |title=The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=8JkyAwAAQBAJ |series=Oxford Quick Reference |edition=3 |location=Oxford |publisher=] |publication-date=2009 |isbn=978-0-19-101827-5 |access-date=14 September 2019 |quote=Industrial capitalism, which Marx dates from the last third of the eighteenth century, finally establishes the domination of the capitalist mode of production. |archive-date=27 July 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200727163404/https://books.google.com/books?id=8JkyAwAAQBAJ |url-status=live}}</ref>
] allowed cheap production of household items using ], while rapid population growth created sustained demand for commodities. Globalization in this period was decisively shaped by 18th-century ].<ref>{{Cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | authorlink= Paul James (academic) | last2= Gills | first2= Barry | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism | url= https://www.academia.edu/4199690/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol._1_Global_Markets_and_Capitalism_editor_with_Barry_Gills_Sage_Publications_London_2007 | publisher= Sage Publications | location= London}}</ref>


Industrial Britain eventually abandoned the ] policy formerly prescribed by mercantilism. In the 19th century, ] (1804–1865) and ] (1811–1889), who based their beliefs on the ], initiated a movement to lower ].<ref name="laissezf">{{cite web |title=Laissez-faire |url=http://www.bartleby.com/65/la/laissezf.html |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081202050426/http://www.bartleby.com/65/la/laissezf.html |archive-date=2 December 2008}}</ref> In the 1840s Britain adopted a less protectionist policy, with the 1846 repeal of the ] and the 1849 repeal of the ].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Burnham |first1=Peter |author1-link=Peter Burnham |year=1996 |chapter=Capitalism |editor1-last=McLean |editor1-first=Iain |editor2-last=McMillan |editor2-first=Alistair |title=The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=8JkyAwAAQBAJ |series=Oxford Quick Reference |edition=3 |location=Oxford |publisher=] |publication-date=2009 |isbn=978-0-19-101827-5 |access-date=14 September 2019 |quote=For most analysts, mid- to late-nineteenth century Britain is seen as the apotheosis of the laissez-faire phase of capitalism. This phase took off in Britain in the 1840s with the repeal of the Corn Laws, and the Navigation Acts, and the passing of the Banking Act. |archive-date=27 July 2020|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200727163404/https://books.google.com/books?id=8JkyAwAAQBAJ |url-status=live}}</ref> Britain reduced tariffs and ], in line with David Ricardo's advocacy of ].
After the ] and ]s and the completion of British conquest of India, vast populations of these regions became ready consumers of European exports. Also in this period, areas of sub-Saharan Africa and the Pacific islands were incorporated into the world system. Meanwhile, the conquest of new parts of the globe, notably sub-Saharan Africa, by Europeans yielded valuable natural resources such as ], ] and ] and helped fuel trade and investment between the European imperial powers, their colonies, and the United States.


=== Modernity ===
<blockquote>The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea, the various products of the whole earth, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep. Militarism and imperialism of racial and cultural rivalries were little more than the amusements of his daily newspaper. What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man was that age which came to an end in August 1914.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/shared/minitext/tr_show01.html |title=PBS.org |publisher=PBS.org |date=24 October 1929 |accessdate=31 July 2010}}</ref></blockquote>
] formed the financial basis of the international economy from 1870 to 1914.]]


Broader processes of ] carried capitalism across the world. By the beginning of the nineteenth century, a series of loosely connected market systems had come together as a relatively integrated global system, in turn intensifying processes of economic and other globalization.<ref name="SAGE Publications">{{cite book |year=2007 |last1=James |first1=Paul |author-link=Paul James (academic) |last2=Gills |first2=Barry |title=Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism |url=https://www.academia.edu/4199690 |publisher=] |location=London |page=xxxiii}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies |url=http://s-space.snu.ac.kr/bitstream/10371/93716/1/04_Osariyekemwen%20Igiebor.pdf |journal=Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies: The Case of Nigeria |pages=84 |access-date=31 July 2020 |archive-date=20 March 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200320071239/http://s-space.snu.ac.kr/bitstream/10371/93716/1/04_Osariyekemwen%20Igiebor.pdf |url-status=live}}</ref> Late in the 20th century, capitalism overcame a challenge by ] and is now the encompassing system worldwide,<ref name="britannica">{{cite book |title=Capitalism |publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica |url=https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/93927/capitalism |date=10 November 2014 |access-date=24 March 2015 |archive-date=29 June 2011 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110629021539/https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/93927/capitalism |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=James |first=Fulcher |title=Capitalism, A Very Short Introduction |quote=In one respect there can, however, be little doubt that capitalism has gone global and that is in the elimination of alternative systems |pages=99 |publisher=] |date=2004 |isbn=978-0-19-280218-7}}</ref> with the ] as its dominant form in the industrialized Western world.
In this period, the global financial system was mainly tied to the ]. The ] first formally adopted this standard in 1821. Soon to follow were ] in 1853, ] in 1865, the ] and Germany ('']'') in 1873. New technologies, such as the ], the ], the ], the ] and ] allowed goods and information to move around the world at an unprecedented degree.<ref>Michael D. Bordo, Barry Eichengreen, Douglas A. Irwin. ''Is Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago?'' NBER {{clarify|date=April 2016}} Working Paper No. 7195. June 1999.</ref>


] allowed cheap production of household items using ], while rapid ] created sustained demand for commodities. The ] of the 18th-century decisively shaped globalization.<ref name="SAGE Publications" /><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Thomas |first1=Martin |last2=Thompson |first2=Andrew |date=1 January 2014 |title=Empire and Globalisation: from 'High Imperialism' to Decolonisation |journal=The International History Review |volume=36 |issue=1 |pages=142–170 |doi=10.1080/07075332.2013.828643 |s2cid=153987517 |issn=0707-5332|doi-access=free }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=Globalization and Empire |url=https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/47230635.pdf |journal=Globalization and Empire |access-date=31 July 2020 |archive-date=23 September 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063531/https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/47230635.pdf |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=Europe and the causes of globalization |url=https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/7045619.pdf |journal=Europe and the Causes of Globalization, 1790 to 2000 |access-date=31 July 2020 |archive-date=7 December 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171207091124/https://core.ac.uk/download/pdf/7045619.pdf |url-status=live}}</ref>
] ] (1963)]]
In the period following the global depression of the 1930s, the state played an increasingly prominent role in the capitalistic system throughout much of the world. The postwar boom ended in the late 1960s and early 1970s, and the situation was worsened by the rise of ].<ref>{{cite book |author=Barnes, Trevor J.|title=Reading economic geography|publisher=Blackwell Publishing|isbn=0-631-23554-X|page=127|year=2004}}</ref> ], a modification of Keynesianism that is more compatible with laissez-faire, gained increasing prominence in the capitalist world, especially under the leadership of ] in the U.S. and ] in the UK in the 1980s. Public and political interest began shifting away from the so-called ] concerns of Keynes's managed capitalism to a focus on individual choice, called "remarketized capitalism".<ref name="Fulcher, James 2004">Fulcher, James. ''Capitalism''. 1st {{abbr|ed.|edition}} New York, Oxford University Press, 2004.</ref>


After the ] and ]s (1839–60) by ] and ] and the completion of the ] conquest of India by 1858 and the ] conquest of ], ] and ] by 1887, vast populations of Asia became consumers of European exports. Europeans colonized areas of Africa and the Pacific islands. Colonisation by Europeans, notably of Africa by the British and French, yielded valuable natural resources such as ], ] and ] and helped fuel trade and investment between the European imperial powers, their colonies and the United States:
According to Harvard academic ] a new genus of capitalism, ] monetizes data acquired through ].<ref>{{cite web|last1=Powles|first1=Julia|title=Google and Microsoft have made a pact to protect surveillance capitalism|url=https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2016/may/02/google-microsoft-pact-antitrust-surveillance-capitalism|publisher=The Guardian|accessdate=9 February 2017|date=2 May 2016}}</ref><ref name=faz1>{{cite web|last1=Zuboff|first1=Shoshana|title=Google as a Fortune Teller: The Secrets of Surveillance Capitalism|url=http://www.faz.net/aktuell/feuilleton/debatten/the-digital-debate/shoshana-zuboff-secrets-of-surveillance-capitalism-14103616.html?printPagedArticle=true|publisher=Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung|accessdate=9 February 2017|date=5 March 2016}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|last1=Sterling|first1=Bruce|title=Shoshanna Zuboff condemning Google "surveillance capitalism"|url=https://www.wired.com/beyond-the-beyond/2016/03/shoshanna-zuboff-condemning-google-surveillance-capitalism/|publisher=WIRED|accessdate=9 February 2017}}</ref> She states it was first discovered and consolidated at ], emerged due to the "coupling of the vast powers of the ] with the radical indifference and intrinsic narcissism of the ] and its ] vision that have dominated commerce for at least three decades, especially in the Anglo economies"<ref name=faz1/> and depends on the global architecture of computer mediation which produces a distributed and largely uncontested new expression of power she calls "Big Other".<ref name=ssrn>{{cite journal|last1=Zuboff|first1=Shoshana|title=Big other: surveillance capitalism and the prospects of an information civilization|journal=Journal of Information Technology|date=9 April 2015|volume=30|issue=1|pages=75–89|doi=10.1057/jit.2015.5|ssrn=2594754|accessdate=|publisher=Social Science Research Network}}</ref>


{{blockquote|The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea, the various products of the whole earth, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep. Militarism and imperialism of racial and cultural rivalries were little more than the amusements of his daily newspaper. What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man was that age which came to an end in August 1914.<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/shared/minitext/tr_show01.html |title=Commanding Heights: Episode One: The Battle of Ideas |publisher=] |date=24 October 1929 |access-date=31 July 2010 |archive-date=30 March 2010 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100330093746/http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/shared/minitext/tr_show01.html |url-status=live}}</ref>}}
==== Relationship to democracy ====
] is one of the main examples of ] in the 21st century]]
The relationship between ] and capitalism is a contentious area in theory and in popular political movements. The extension of universal adult male ] in 19th century Britain occurred along with the development of industrial capitalism, and democracy became widespread at the same time as capitalism, leading capitalists to posit a causal or mutual relationship between them.<ref>{{cite web|last1=Kaminski|first1=Joseph|title=Capitalism and the Industrial Revolution|url=http://josephkaminski.net/2013/10/30/capitalism-and-industrial-revolution/|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150128024314/http://josephkaminski.net/2013/10/30/capitalism-and-industrial-revolution/|dead-url=yes|archive-date=28 January 2015}}</ref> However, in the 20th century, according to some authors, capitalism also accompanied a variety of political formations quite distinct from liberal democracies, including ] regimes, absolute monarchies, and single-party states.<ref name="Burnham" /> Democratic peace theory asserts that democracies seldom fight other democracies, but critics of that theory suggest that this may be because of political similarity or stability rather than because they are democratic or capitalist.


From the 1870s to the early 1920s, the global financial system was mainly tied to the ].<ref>{{cite book|last=Eichengreen|first=Barry|author-link=Barry Eichengreen|date=6 August 2019|title=Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System|edition=3rd|publisher=]|doi=10.2307/j.ctvd58rxg|isbn=978-0-691-19458-5|s2cid=240840930 |lccn=2019018286}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|last1=Eichengreen|first1=Barry|author-link=Barry Eichengreen|last2=Esteves|first2=Rui Pedro|date=2021|editor1-last=Fukao|editor1-first=Kyoji|editor2-last=Broadberry|editor2-first=Stephen|editor2-link=Stephen Broadberry|section=International Finance|title=The Cambridge Economic History of the Modern World|publisher=]|volume=2: ''1870 to the Present''|pages=501–525|isbn=978-1-107-15948-8}}</ref> The United Kingdom first formally adopted this standard in 1821. Soon to follow were ] in 1853, ] in 1865, the United States and Germany ('']'') in 1873. New technologies, such as the ], the ], the ], the ] and ]s allowed goods and information to move around the world to an unprecedented degree.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.nber.org/papers/w7195 |last1=Bordo |first1=Michael D. |author1-link=Michael D. Bordo |last2=Eichengreen |first2=Barry |author2-link=Barry Eichengreen |last3=Irwin |first3=Douglas A. |title=Is Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago? |series=NBER |number=Working Paper No. 7195 |date=June 1999|doi=10.3386/w7195 }}</ref>
Moderate critics argue that though economic growth under capitalism has led to democracy in the past, it may not do so in the future, as ] regimes have been able to manage economic growth without making concessions to greater political freedom.<ref>{{cite web|author=Mesquita, Bruce Bueno de |url=http://www.foreignaffairs.org/20050901faessay84507/bruce-bueno-de-mesquita-george-w-downs/development-and-democracy.html |title=Development and Democracy |date=September 2005 |accessdate=26 February 2008 |work=Foreign Affairs |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20080220154505/http://www.foreignaffairs.org/20050901faessay84507/bruce-bueno-de-mesquita-george-w-downs/development-and-democracy.html |archivedate=20 February 2008 |df= }}</ref><ref>{{cite news|author=Single, Joseph T. |url=http://www10.nytimes.com/cfr/international/20040901facomment_v83n4_siegle-weinstein-halperin.html?_r=5&oref=slogin&oref=slogin&oref=slogin&oref=slogin |title=Why Democracies Excel |date=September 2004 |accessdate=26 February 2008 |work=The New York Times }}{{dead link|date=June 2017 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}</ref>


In the United States, the term "capitalist" primarily referred to powerful businessmen<ref>{{Cite book |last=Andrews |first=Thomas G. |title=Killing for Coal: America's Deadliest Labor War |publisher=] |year=2008 |isbn=978-0-674-03101-2 |location=Cambridge |page=64 |author-link=Thomas G. Andrews (historian)}}</ref> until the 1920s due to widespread societal skepticism and criticism of capitalism and its most ardent supporters.
One of the biggest supporters of the idea that capitalism promotes political freedom, Milton Friedman, argues that competitive capitalism allows economic and political power to be separate, ensuring that they do not clash with one another. This idea has been challenged given the current influence capitalist lobbying has had on policy in the United States. The approval of ], has led people to question the very idea that competitive capitalism promotes political freedom. The ruling on Citizens United allows corporations to spend undisclosed and unregulated amounts of money on political campaigns, shifting outcomes to the interests and undermining true democracy. As explained in Robin Hahnel’s writings, the centerpiece of the ideological defense of the free market system is the concept of economic freedom, and that supporters equate economic democracy with economic freedom and claim that only the free market system can provide economic freedom. According to Hahnel, there are a few objections to the premise that capitalism offers freedom through economic freedom. These objections are guided by critical questions about who or what decides whose freedoms are more protected. Often, the question of inequality is brought up when discussing how well capitalism promotes democracy. An argument that could stand is that economic growth can lead to inequality given that capital can be acquired at different rates by different people. In '']'', ] of the ] asserts that inequality is the inevitable consequence of economic growth in a capitalist economy and the resulting ] can destabilize democratic societies and undermine the ideals of social justice upon which they are built.<ref>] (2014). ''Capital in the Twenty-First Century.'' ]. {{ISBN|0-674-43000-X}} p. 571.</ref> ], ] (except for ]), and other leftists argue that capitalism is incompatible with democracy since capitalism according to Marx entails "dictatorship of the ]" (owners of the means of production) while democracy entails rule by the people.


] ] (1963)]]
States with capitalistic economic systems have thrived under political regimes deemed to be authoritarian or oppressive. Singapore has a successful open market economy as a result of its competitive, business-friendly climate and robust rule of law; nonetheless, it often comes under fire for (1) its brand of government, which, though democratic and consistently one of the least corrupt,<ref>{{cite web|title=Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015|url=https://www.transparency.org/country/#SGP|website=Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015 – By Country / Territory|publisher=Transparency International|accessdate=20 September 2016}}</ref> operates largely under a one-party rule, and (2) not vigorously defending freedom of expression, given its government-regulated press, as well as penchant for upholding laws protecting ethnic and religious harmony, judicial dignity and personal reputation. The private (capitalist) sector in the People's Republic of China has grown exponentially and thrived since its inception, despite having an authoritarian government. ]'s rule in Chile led to economic growth and high levels of inequality<ref>] (2008). ''].'' ]. {{ISBN|0-312-42799-9}} .</ref> by using authoritarian means to create a safe environment for investment and capitalism.


Contemporary capitalist societies developed in the West from 1950 to the present and this type of system continues throughout the world—relevant examples started in the ], ], ], ], and others. At this stage most capitalist markets are considered{{by whom|date=July 2021}} developed and characterized by developed private and public markets for equity and debt, a high ] (as characterized by the ] and the ]), large institutional investors and a well-funded ]. A significant ] has emerged{{when|date=July 2021}} and decides on a significant proportion of investments and other decisions. A different future than that envisioned by Marx has started to emerge—explored and described by ] in the United Kingdom in his 1956 book '']''<ref>{{cite book |last=Crosland |first=Anthony |title=The Future of Socialism |publisher=Jonathan Cape |year=1956 |location=United Kingdom}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref> and by ] in North America in his 1958 book '']'',<ref>{{cite book |last=Galbraith |first=John Kenneth |title=The Affluent Society |publisher=] |year=1958 |location=United States}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref> 90 years after Marx's research on the state of capitalism in 1867.<ref>{{cite book |last=Shiller |first=Robert |title=Finance and The Good Society |publisher=] |year=2012 |location=United States}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref>
=== Varieties of capitalism ===
Peter A. Hall and ] argued that modern economies have developed two different forms of capitalism: liberal market economies (or LME) (e.g. US, UK, Canada, New Zealand, Ireland) and coordinated market economies (CME) (e.g. Germany, Japan, Sweden, Austria). Those two types can be distinguished by the primary way in which firms coordinate with each other and other actors, such as ]. In LMEs firms primarily coordinate their endeavors by way of hierarchies and market mechanisms. Coordinated market economies more heavily rely on non-market forms of interaction in the coordination of their relationship with other actors (for a detailed description see '']''). These two forms of capitalisms developed different ], ] and ], ], inter-firm relations and relations with employees. The existence of these different forms of capitalism has important societal effects, especially in periods of crisis and instability. Since the early 2000s the number of labor market outsiders has rapidly grown in Europe, especially among the youth, potentially influencing social and political participation. Using varieties of capitalism theory it is possible to disentangle the different effects on social and political participation that an increase of labor market outsiders has in liberal and coordinated market economies (Ferragina et al. 2016).<ref>Emanuele Ferragina et al.(2016). "Outsiderness and participation in liberal market economies." PACO ''The Open Journal of Sociopolitical Studies'', 9, 986–1014 http://scholar.google.fr/scholar_url?url=http%3A%2F%2Fsiba-ese.unisalento.it%2Findex.php%2Fpaco%2Farticle%2Fdownload%2F16664%2F14327&hl=fr&sa=T&ei=AN-iWPD-EIupmAHrx5vACw&scisig=AAGBfm3_dOCLibWFNHNtG62FKywcq7PxNA&nossl=1&ws=1920x909</ref> The social and political disaffection, especially among the youth, seems to be more pronounced in liberal than coordinated market economies. This signals an important problem for liberal market economies in a period of crisis. If the market does not provide consistent job opportunities (as it has in previous decades), the shortcomings of liberal social security systems may depress social and political participation even further than in other capitalist economies.


The ] ended in the late 1960s and early 1970s and the economic situation grew worse with the rise of ].<ref>{{cite book |last=Barnes |first=Trevor J. |title=Reading economic geography |publisher=] |isbn=978-0-631-23554-5 |page=127 |year=2004}}</ref> ], a modification of ] that is more compatible with ''laissez-faire'' analyses, gained increasing prominence in the capitalist world, especially under the years in office of ] in the United States (1981–1989) and of ] in the United Kingdom (1979–1990). Public and political interest began shifting away from the so-called ] concerns of Keynes's managed capitalism to a focus on individual ], called "remarketized capitalism".<ref name="Fulcher, James 2004">{{cite book |last=Fulcher |first=James |title=Capitalism |edition=1st |location=New York |publisher=] |date=2004}}{{page needed|date=December 2023}}</ref>
== Characteristics ==
{{Further information|Academic perspectives on capitalism}}Capitalism is "production for exchange" driven by the desire for personal accumulation of money receipts in such exchanges, mediated by free markets. The markets themselves are driven by the needs and wants of consumers and those of society as a whole. Contemporary mainstream economics, particularly that associated with the ], holds that by an "]",<ref>Adam Smith, often mis-attributed in this sense. See the ] section for what Smith actually said.</ref> through little more than the freedom of the market, is able to match social production to these needs and desires.<ref name="xxx31"/>


The end of the ] and the ] allowed for capitalism to become a truly global system in a way not seen since before ]. The development of the ] global economy would have been impossible without the fall of ].<ref>{{cite book |last=Gerstle |first=Gary |author-link=Gary Gerstle |date=2022 |title=The Rise and Fall of the Neoliberal Order: America and the World in the Free Market Era |url=https://global.oup.com/academic/product/the-rise-and-fall-of-the-neoliberal-order-9780197519646?cc=us&lang=en& |location= |publisher=] |pages=10–12 |isbn=978-0-19-751964-6}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Bartel |first=Fritz |date=2022 |title=The Triumph of Broken Promises: The End of the Cold War and the Rise of Neoliberalism |url=https://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=978-0-674-97678-8 |location= |publisher=] |pages=5–6, 19 |isbn=978-0-674-97678-8}}</ref>
=== Summary ===
In general, capitalism as an economic system and mode of production can be summarised by the following:<ref>{{cite web|url=http://publishing.cdlib.org/ucpressebooks/view?docId=ft3n39n8x3&chunk.id=d0e1212&toc.id=&brand=ucpress|title=Althusser and the Renewal of Marxist Social Theory|publisher=}}</ref>
* ]:<ref name=ch32>{{cite web|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch32.htm|title=Economic Manuscripts: Capital Vol. I – Chapter Thirty Two|first=Karl|last=Marx|publisher=}}</ref> Production for profit and accumulation as the implicit purpose of all or most of production, constriction or elimination of production formerly carried out on a common social or private household basis.<ref name=xxx31 />
* ]: Production for exchange on a market; to maximise ] instead of ].
* ] of the means of production:<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54"/>
* High levels of ].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/lmac/self-employed-workers-in-the-uk/2014/rep-self-employed-workers-in-the-uk-2014.html#tab-Self-employed-workers-in-the-UK---2014|title= UK Government Web Archive – The National Archives|first=Internet Memory|last=Foundation|publisher=}}</ref>
* The ] of money to make a profit.<ref>James Fulcher, ''Capitalism A Very Short Introduction'', "the investment of money in order to make a profit, the essential feature of capitalism", p. 14, Oxford, 2004, {{ISBN|978-0-19-280218-7}}.</ref>
* The use of the ] to allocate resources between competing uses.<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54"/>


Harvard Kennedy School economist Dani Rodrik distinguishes between three historical variants of capitalism:<ref>{{citation |last=Rodrik |first=Dani |title=Capitalism 3.0 |date=2009 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt46mtqx.23 |work=Aftershocks |volume= |pages=185–193 |editor-last=Hemerijck |editor-first=Anton |publisher=] |jstor=j.ctt46mtqx.23 |isbn=978-90-8964-192-2 |access-date=14 January 2021 |editor2-last=Knapen |editor2-first=Ben |editor3-last=van Doorne |editor3-first=Ellen}}</ref>
=== The market ===
* Capitalism 1.0 during the 19th century entailed largely unregulated markets with a minimal role for the state (aside from national defense, and protecting property rights);
] at each price (demand, D): this results in a market equilibrium, with a given quantity (Q) sold of the product, whereas a rise in demand would result in an increase in price and an increase in output]]
* Capitalism 2.0 during the post-World War II years entailed Keynesianism, a substantial role for the state in regulating markets, and strong welfare states;
In free-market and '']'' forms of capitalism, markets are used most extensively with minimal or no regulation over the pricing mechanism. In mixed economies, which are almost universal today,<ref>James Fulcher, ''Capitalism A Very Short Introduction'', "...in the wake of the 1970 crisis, the neo-liberal model of capitalism became intellectually and ideologically dominant", p. 58, Oxford, 2004, {{ISBN|978-0-19-280218-7}}.</ref> markets continue to play a dominant role but are regulated to some extent by government in order to correct ]s, promote ], conserve ]s, fund ] and ] or for other reasons. In ] systems, markets are relied upon the least, with the state relying heavily on ] or indirect economic planning to accumulate capital.
* Capitalism 2.1 entailed a combination of unregulated markets, globalization, and various national obligations by states.


==== Relationship to democracy ====
Supply is the amount of a good or service produced by a firm and which is available for sale. Demand is the amount that people are willing to buy at a specific price. Prices tend to rise when demand exceeds supply, and fall when supply exceeds demand. In theory, the market is able to coordinate itself when a new equilibrium price and quantity is reached.
The relationship between ] and capitalism is a contentious area in theory and in popular political movements.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Milner |first1=Helen V |title=Is Global Capitalism Compatible with Democracy? Inequality, Insecurity, and Interdependence |journal=] |date=2021 |volume=65 |issue=4 |pages=1097–1110 |doi=10.1093/isq/sqab056 |doi-access=free}}</ref> The extension of adult-male ] in 19th-century Britain occurred along with the development of industrial capitalism and ] became widespread at the same time as capitalism, leading capitalists to posit a causal or mutual relationship between them. However, according to some authors in the 20th-century, capitalism also accompanied a variety of political formations quite distinct from liberal democracies, including ] regimes, ] and ].<ref name="Burnham" /> ] asserts that democracies seldom fight other democracies, but others suggest this may be because of political similarity or stability, rather than because they are "democratic" or "capitalist". Critics argue that though economic growth under capitalism has led to democracy, it may not do so in the future as ] régimes have been able to manage economic growth using some of capitalism's competitive principles<ref>{{cite magazine |first=Gady |last=Epstein |title=The Winners And Losers in Chinese Capitalism |url=https://www.forbes.com/sites/gadyepstein/2010/08/31/the-winners-and-losers-in-chinese-capitalism/ |magazine=] |access-date=28 October 2015 |archive-date=5 November 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151105210914/http://www.forbes.com/sites/gadyepstein/2010/08/31/the-winners-and-losers-in-chinese-capitalism/ |url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite news |title=The rise of state capitalism |url=http://www.economist.com/node/21543160 |newspaper=] |access-date=24 October 2015 |issn=0013-0613 |archive-date=15 June 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200615124603/https://www.economist.com/leaders/2012/01/21/the-rise-of-state-capitalism |url-status=live}}</ref> without making concessions to greater ].<ref>{{cite web |last=Mesquita |first=Bruce Bueno de |url=http://www.foreignaffairs.org/20050901faessay84507/bruce-bueno-de-mesquita-george-w-downs/development-and-democracy.html |title=Development and Democracy |date=September 2005 |access-date=26 February 2008 |work=] |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080220154505/http://www.foreignaffairs.org/20050901faessay84507/bruce-bueno-de-mesquita-george-w-downs/development-and-democracy.html |archive-date=20 February 2008}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Siegle |first1=Joseph |last2=Weinstein |first2=Michael |last3=Halperin |first3=Morton |date=1 September 2004 |title=Why Democracies Excel |url=http://www.mafhoum.com/press7/212S28.pdf |journal=] |volume=83 |issue=5 |pages=57 |doi=10.2307/20034067 |jstor=20034067 |access-date=26 August 2018 |archive-date=12 April 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190412055541/http://www.mafhoum.com/press7/212S28.pdf |url-status=live}}</ref>


Political scientists ] and ] see democracy and capitalism as mutually supportive.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Iversen |first1=Torben |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctv4g1r3n |title=Democracy and Prosperity: Reinventing Capitalism through a Turbulent Century |last2=Soskice |first2=David |date=2019 |publisher=] |jstor=j.ctv4g1r3n |isbn=978-0-691-18273-5}}</ref> ] argued in ''On Democracy'' that capitalism was beneficial for democracy because economic growth and a large middle class were good for democracy.<ref name=":0a">{{cite book |last=Dahl |first=Robert A. |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ZG4JEAAAQBAJ |title=On Democracy |date=2020 |publisher=] |isbn=978-0-300-25799-1 |language=en}}</ref> He also argued that a market economy provided a substitute for government control of the economy, which reduces the risks of tyranny and authoritarianism.<ref name=":0a" />
Competition arises when more than one producer is trying to sell the same or similar products to the same buyers. In capitalist theory, competition leads to innovation and more affordable prices. Without competition, a ] or ] may develop. A monopoly occurs when a firm supplies the total output in the market; the firm can therefore limit output and raise prices because it has no fear of competition. A cartel is a group of firms that act together in a monopolistic manner to control output and prices.


In his book '']'' (1944), ] (1899–1992) asserted that the free-market understanding of ] as present in capitalism is a requisite of ]. He argued that the market mechanism is the only way of deciding what to produce and how to distribute the items without using coercion. ] and ] also promoted this view.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Pryor |first1=Frederic L. |title=Capitalism and freedom? |journal=Economic Systems |date=2010 |volume=34 |issue=1 |pages=91–104 |doi=10.1016/j.ecosys.2009.09.003}}</ref> Friedman claimed that centralized economic operations are always accompanied by ]. In his view, transactions in a market economy are voluntary and the wide diversity that voluntary activity permits is a fundamental threat to repressive ]s and greatly diminishes their power to coerce. Some of Friedman's views were shared by ], who believed that capitalism was vital for freedom to survive and thrive.<ref>{{cite journal |first=Friedrich |last=Hayek |author-link=Friedrich Hayek |title=The Road to Serfdom |journal=] |volume=154 |issue=3911 |pages=473–474 |publisher=] |year=1944 |isbn=978-0-226-32061-8 |bibcode=1944Natur.154..473C |doi=10.1038/154473a0 |s2cid=4071358}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Bellamy |first=Richard |title=The Cambridge History of Twentieth-Century Political Thought |publisher=] |year=2003 |isbn=978-0-521-56354-3 |page=60}}</ref> ], an American ] that conducts international research on, and advocates for, democracy, political freedom and ], has argued that "there is a high and statistically significant correlation between the level of political freedom ] and economic freedom ]".<ref>{{cite book |first=Adrian |last=Karatnycky |title=Freedom in the World: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties |publisher=] |date=2001 |isbn=978-0-7658-0101-2 |page=11}}</ref>
Efforts are made by government to prevent the creation of monopolies and cartels. In 1890, the Sherman Anti-Trust Act became the first legislation passed by the U.S. Congress to limit monopolies. <ref>{{Cite news|url=http://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/monopoly.asp|title=Monopoly|last=Staff|first=Investopedia|date=24 November 2003|work=Investopedia|access-date=2 March 2017|language=en-US}}</ref>


In '']'' (2013), ] of the ] asserted that inequality is the inevitable consequence of economic growth in a capitalist economy and the resulting ] can destabilize democratic societies and undermine the ideals of social justice upon which they are built.<ref>{{cite book |author-link=Thomas Piketty |last=Piketty |first=Thomas |date=2014 |title=Capital in the Twenty-First Century |publisher=] |isbn=978-0-674-43000-6 |page=571}}</ref>
=== Profit motive ===
The ] is a theory in capitalism which posits that the ultimate goal of a business is to make money. Stated differently, the reason for a business's existence is to turn a profit. The profit motive functions on the ], or the theory that individuals tend to pursue what is in their own best interests. Accordingly, businesses seek to benefit themselves and/or their shareholders by maximizing profits.


States with capitalistic economic systems have thrived under political regimes deemed to be authoritarian or oppressive. ] has a successful open market economy as a result of its competitive, business-friendly climate and robust rule of law. Nonetheless, it often comes under fire for its style of government which, though democratic and consistently one of the least corrupt,<ref>{{cite web |title=Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015 |url=https://www.transparency.org/country/#SGP |website=Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015 – By Country / Territory |publisher=Transparency International |access-date=20 September 2016 |archive-date=31 March 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160331114640/http://www.transparency.org/country/#SGP |url-status=dead}}</ref> operates largely under a one-party rule. Furthermore, it does not vigorously defend freedom of expression as evidenced by its government-regulated ], and its penchant for upholding laws protecting ethnic and religious harmony, judicial dignity and personal reputation. The private (capitalist) sector in the People's Republic of China has grown exponentially and thrived since its inception, despite having an authoritarian government. ]'s ] led to economic growth and high levels of inequality<ref>] (2008). ''].'' ]. {{ISBN|0-312-42799-9}} {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150319071518/http://books.google.com/books?id=PwHUAq5LPOQC&lpg=PP1&pg=PA105 |date=19 March 2015 }}.</ref> by using authoritarian means to create a safe environment for investment and capitalism. Similarly, ]'s authoritarian reign and ] of the ] allowed for the expansion of capitalism in ].<ref>{{cite journal |last=Farid |first=Hilmar |date=2005 |title=Indonesia's original sin: mass killings and capitalist expansion, 1965–66 |journal=] |volume=6 |issue=1 |pages=3–16 |doi=10.1080/1462394042000326879 |s2cid= 145130614}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Robinson |first=Geoffrey B. |date=2018 |title=The Killing Season: A History of the Indonesian Massacres, 1965–66 |url=https://press.princeton.edu/titles/11135.html |publisher=] |page=177 |isbn=978-1-4008-8886-3 |access-date=1 August 2018 |archive-date=19 April 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190419011656/https://press.princeton.edu/titles/11135.html |url-status=live}}</ref>
In capitalist theoretics, the profit motive is said to ensure that resources are being allocated efficiently. For instance, ] ] explains: “If there is no profit in making an article, it is a sign that the labor and capital devoted to its production are misdirected: the value of the resources that must be used up in making the article is greater than the value of the article itself."<ref>Hazlitt, Henry. "The Function of Profits". ''Economics in One Lesson''. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. Web. 22 April 2013.</ref> In other words, profits let companies know whether an item is worth producing. Theoretically in free and competitive markets, maximising profits ensures that resources are not wasted.


The term "capitalism" in its modern sense is often attributed to ].<ref name="Scott">{{cite book |title=Industrialism: A Dictionary of Sociology |last=Scott |first=John |publisher=] |year=2005}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |title="capitalism, n.2". OED Online |url=http://www.oed.com/view/Entry/27454?rskey=ZVI1hr&result=2&isAdvanced=false |access-date=19 January 2013 |archive-date=23 September 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063611/https://www.oed.com/start;jsessionid=A9CBE07460C68ED291D7D6CDCE84A1B1?authRejection=true&url=%2Fview%2FEntry%2F27454%3Frskey%3DZVI1hr%26result%3D2%26isAdvanced%3Dfalse |url-status=live}}</ref> In his '']'', Marx analyzed the "]" using a method of understanding today known as ]. However, Marx himself rarely used the term "capitalism" while it was used twice in the more political interpretations of his work, primarily authored by his collaborator ]. In the 20th century, defenders of the capitalist system often replaced the term "capitalism" with phrases such as free enterprise and private enterprise and replaced "capitalist" with ] and ] in reaction to the negative connotations associated with capitalism.<ref name="Williams 1983 51">{{cite book |last=Williams |first=Raymond |title=Keywords: A vocabulary of culture and society, revised edition |publisher=] |year=1983 |isbn=978-0-19-520469-8 |page= |chapter=Capitalism |chapter-url=https://archive.org/details/keywordsvocabula00willrich/page/51}}</ref>
=== Private property ===
The relationship between the ], its formal mechanisms, and capitalist societies has been debated in many fields of social and political theory, with active discussion since the 19th century. ] is a contemporary economist who has argued that an important characteristic of capitalism is the functioning state protection of property rights in a formal property system where ownership and transactions are clearly recorded.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/03/desoto.htm |title=The mystery of capital|author=Hernando de Soto|accessdate=26 February 2008}}</ref>


== Characteristics ==
According to de Soto, this is the process by which physical assets are transformed into capital, which in turn may be used in many more ways and much more efficiently in the market economy. A number of Marxian economists have argued that the ] in England, and similar legislation elsewhere, were an integral part of capitalist ] and that specific legal frameworks of private land ownership have been integral to the development of capitalism.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch27.htm |title=Capital, v. 1. Part VIII: primitive accumulation|author=Karl Marx|accessdate=26 February 2008}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |author=N. F. R. Crafts |title=Enclosure and labor supply revisited |journal=Explorations in economic history |issue=15 |date=April 1978 |pages=172–83 |doi=10.1016/0014-4983(78)90019-0 |volume=15}}</ref>
{{further|Academic perspectives on capitalism}}
In general, capitalism as an economic system and mode of production can be summarized by the following:<ref>{{cite web|url=http://publishing.cdlib.org/ucpressebooks/view?docId=ft3n39n8x3&chunk.id=d0e1212&toc.id=&brand=ucpress |title=Althusser and the Renewal of Marxist Social Theory |access-date=24 March 2015 |archive-date=2 April 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150402094835/http://publishing.cdlib.org/ucpressebooks/view?docId=ft3n39n8x3&chunk.id=d0e1212&toc.id=&brand=ucpress |url-status=live}}</ref>
* ]:<ref name=ch32>{{cite book|url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch32.htm |title=Economic Manuscripts: Capital Vol. I |chapter=Thirty Two |first=Karl |last=Marx |author-link=Karl Marx |access-date=24 March 2015 |via=] |archive-date=21 February 2015 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150221104326/https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch32.htm |url-status=live}}</ref> production for profit and accumulation as the implicit purpose of all or most of production, constriction or elimination of production formerly carried out on a common social or private household basis.<ref name=xxx31 />
* ]: production for exchange on a market; to maximize ] instead of ].
* Exchange of goods or services, can be enabled by ]s.<ref name="y015">{{cite book | last=Goldberg | first=Victor P. | title=The Oxford Handbook of Capitalism | chapter=Contracts | publisher=Oxford University Press | date=21 November 2012 | isbn=978-0-19-539117-6 | doi=10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195391176.013.0010 | pages=250–274}}</ref> Exchange of services can be in form of ].<ref name="Steinfeld 2009 3"/>
* ] of the means of production:<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54" />
* The ] of money to make a profit.<ref>James Fulcher, ''Capitalism A Very Short Introduction'', "the investment of money in order to make a profit, the essential feature of capitalism", p. 14, Oxford, 2004, {{ISBN|978-0-19-280218-7}}.</ref>
* The use of the ] to allocate resources between competing uses.<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54" />
* Economically efficient use of the ] and raw materials due to maximization of value added in the production process.<ref>{{cite book|title=Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life |last=Reisman |first=George |year=1998 |isbn=0-915463-73-3 |publisher=Jameson Books}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|title=History of Economic Thought: A Critical Perspective |last1=Hunt |first1=E.K. |last2=Lautzenheiser |first2=Mark |year=2014 |publisher=PHI Learning |isbn=978-0-7656-2599-1}}</ref>
* Freedom of capitalists to act in their self-interest in managing their business and investments.<ref>{{cite book|title=Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life |last=Reisman |first=George |year=1998 |isbn=978-0-915463-73-2 |publisher=Jameson Books}}</ref>
* Capital suppliance by "the single owner of a firm, or by ]s in the case of a ]."<ref name=":1">{{Cite book |title=The Desk Encyclopedia of World History |publisher=] |year=2006 |isbn=978-0-7394-7809-7 |editor-last=Wright |editor-first=Edmund |location=New York |pages=111–112}}</ref>


=== Market competition === === Market ===
In ] and '']'' forms of capitalism, markets are used most extensively with minimal or no regulation over the pricing mechanism. In mixed economies, which are almost universal today,<ref>James Fulcher, ''Capitalism A Very Short Introduction'', "...in the wake of the 1970 crisis, the neoliberal model of capitalism became intellectually and ideologically dominant", p. 58, Oxford, 2004, {{ISBN|978-0-19-280218-7}}.</ref> markets continue to play a dominant role, but they are regulated to some extent by the state in order to correct ]s, promote ], conserve ]s, fund ] and ] or other rationale. In ] systems, markets are relied upon the least, with the state relying heavily on ] or indirect economic planning to accumulate capital.
{{Main article|Competition (economics)}}
In capitalist economics, market competition is the rivalry among sellers trying to achieve such goals as increasing profits, market share, and sales volume by varying the elements of the ]: price, product, distribution, and promotion. Merriam-Webster defines competition in business as "the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favourable terms".<ref>{{cite web|url=http://m-w.com/dictionary/competition|title=Definition of COMPETITION|publisher=}}</ref> It was described by ] in '']'' (1776) and later economists as allocating productive ]s to their most highly valued uses<ref>], 2008. (]] {{clarify|date=April 2016}} 2008 {{clarify|date=April 2016}}. "competition", '']''. </ref> and encouraging ]. Smith and other ]s before ] were referring to price and non-price rivalry among producers to sell their goods on best terms by bidding of buyers, not necessarily to a large number of sellers nor to a market in final ].<ref>], 2008. "Invisible hand", ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd Edition, v. 4, p. 565. .</ref> Competition is widespread throughout the ]. It is a condition where "buyers tend to compete with other buyers, and sellers tend to compete with other sellers".<ref name=ewot2014 /><!-- p. 102 --> In offering goods for exchange, buyers competitively bid to purchase specific quantities of specific goods which are available, or might be available if sellers were to choose to offer such goods. Similarly, sellers bid against other sellers in offering goods on the market, competing for the attention and exchange resources of buyers. Competition results from ]{{snd}}there is never enough to satisfy all conceivable human wants{{snd}}and occurs "when people strive to meet the criteria that are being used to determine who gets what".<!-- p. 105 --><ref name=ewot2014>{{cite book |last1=Heyne|first1=Paul |last2=Boettke|first2=Peter J. |last3=Prychitko|first3=David L. |title=The Economic Way of Thinking |date=2014 |publisher=Pearson |isbn=978-0-13-299129-2 |pages=102–06 |edition=13th }}<!--|accessdate=24 December 2014 --></ref>


Competition arises when more than one producer is trying to sell the same or similar products to the same buyers. Adherents of the capitalist theory believe that competition leads to innovation and more affordable prices. ] or ] can develop, especially if there is no competition. A monopoly occurs when a firm has exclusivity over a market. Hence, the firm can engage in ] behaviors such as limiting output and raising prices because it has no fear of competition.
=== Reserve army of labour ===
{{Main article|Reserve army of labour}}
In a Marxist analysis of the capitalist economy, the reserve army of labour refers to the ] and ].<ref>Francis Green, “The Reserve Army Hypothesis: A Survey of Empirical Applications”, in Paul Dunne (ed.), ''Quantitative Marxism'', Cambridge, Polity Press, 1991, pp. 123–40.</ref> It is synonymous with "industrial reserve army" or "relative surplus population", except that the unemployed can be defined as those actually looking for work and that the relative surplus population also includes people unable to work. The use of the word "army" refers to the workers being conscripted and regimented in the workplace in a ], under the ].


Governments have implemented legislation for the purpose of preventing the creation of monopolies and cartels. In 1890, the ] became the first legislation passed by the United States Congress to limit monopolies.<ref>{{Cite news|url=http://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/monopoly.asp|title=Monopoly|author=<!--Staff writer(s); no by-line.-->|date=24 November 2003|work=Investopedia|access-date=2 March 2017|language=en-US|archive-date=22 February 2017|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170222204011/http://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/monopoly.asp|url-status=live}}</ref>
Prior to the start of the capitalist era in human history (i.e. before the 1500s), ] on a mass scale rarely existed, other than that caused by natural disasters and wars.<ref>{{cite book |first=John A. |last=Garraty |title=Unemployment in History: Economic Thought and Public Policy |location=New York |publisher=Harper and Row |year=1978 |isbn=0-06-011457-6 }}, chapter 2.</ref> In ancient societies, all people who could work necessarily had to work, otherwise they would starve; a slave or a serf by definition could not become "unemployed". There was normally very little possibility of "earning a crust" without working at all, and the usual attitude toward beggars and idlers was harsh.<ref>Garraty, p. 14.</ref> Children began to work already at a very early age. Indeed, the word "employment" is linguistically a product of the capitalist era. A permanent level of unemployment presupposes a working population which is to a large extent dependent on a wage or salary for a living, without having other means of livelihood, as well as the right of enterprises to hire and fire employees in accordance with commercial or economic conditions. The expression "unemployed" in English, in the sense of "temporarily out of work", dates back to the 1660s; reference to "the unemployed" as a group was first made in 1782; and reference to "unemployment" as a general condition is first attested in 1888.<ref>''Online Etymological Dictionary'', entry "unemployed".</ref>


=== Wage labor ===
The first recorded discussion of the reserve army of labour is in a manuscript written by ]: {{Quotation|Big industry constantly requires a reserve army of unemployed workers for times of ]. The main purpose of the bourgeois in relation to the worker is, of course, to have the commodity labour as cheaply as possible, which is only possible when the supply of this commodity is as large as possible in relation to the demand for it, i.e., when the overpopulation is the greatest. Overpopulation is therefore in the interest of the bourgeoisie, and it gives the workers good advice which it knows to be impossible to carry out. Since capital only increases when it employs workers, the increase of capital involves an increase of the proletariat, and, as we have seen, according to the nature of the relation of capital and labour, the increase of the proletariat must proceed relatively even faster. The... theory... which is also expressed as a law of nature, that population grows faster than the means of subsistence, is the more welcome to the bourgeois as it silences his conscience, makes hard-heartedness into a moral duty and the consequences of society into the consequences of nature, and finally gives him the opportunity to watch the destruction of the proletariat by starvation as calmly as other natural event without bestirring himself, and, on the other hand, to regard the misery of the proletariat as its own fault and to punish it. To be sure, the proletarian can restrain his natural instinct by reason, and so, by moral supervision, halt the law of nature in its injurious course of development. — Karl Marx, '']'', December 1847<ref>, Works of Karl Marx 1847; source: MECW {{clarify|date=April 2016}} Volume 6, p. 415; written: at the end of December 1847; first published: in Russian in the journal Sotsialisticheskoye khozyaistvo, 1924 and in German in the journal Unter dem Banner des Marxismus {{clarify|reason=1924 and ??|date=April 2016}}, 1925.</ref>|sign=|source=}}
{{Main|Wage labor}}
Wage labor, usually referred to as paid work, paid employment, or paid labor, refers to the ] relationship between a ] and an ] in which the worker sells their labor power under a formal or informal ].<ref name="Steinfeld 2009 3">{{Harvnb|Steinfeld|2009|p=3}}: "All labor contracts were/are designed legally to bind a worker in one way or another to fulfill the labor obligations the worker has undertaken. That is one of the principal purposes of labor contracts."</ref> These transactions usually occur in a ] where ]s or ] are ].<ref>{{Harvnb|Deakin|Wilkinson|2005}}</ref>


In exchange for the money paid as wages (usual for short-term work-contracts) or salaries (in permanent employment contracts), the work product generally becomes the ] of the employer. A wage laborer is a person whose primary means of income is from the selling of their labor in this way.<ref>{{cite book|page=278|title=Concise Dictionary of Economics|isbn=978-93-5057-032-6|publisher=V&S Publishers|year=2013|author=Editorial Board|chapter=W}}</ref>
Marx introduced the concept in chapter 25 of the first volume of '']'',<ref></ref> which states:
{{Quotation|Capitalistic accumulation itself... constantly produces, and produces in the direct ratio of its own energy and extent, a relatively redundant population of workers, i.e., a population of greater extent than suffices for the average needs of the ] of capital, and therefore a surplus-population... It is the absolute interest of every capitalist to press a given quantity of labour out of a smaller, rather than a greater number of labourers, if the cost is about the same... The more extended the scale of production, the stronger this motive. Its force increases with the accumulation of capital.|sign=|source=}}


=== Profit motive ===
His argument is that as capitalism develops, the ] will increase, which means that the mass of ] grows faster than the mass of ]. Fewer workers can produce all that is necessary for society's requirements. In addition, capital will become more concentrated and centralised in fewer hands. This being the ''absolute'' historical tendency, part of the working population will tend to become ''surplus'' to the requirements of ] over time. Paradoxically, the larger the wealth of society, the larger the industrial reserve army will become. Marx called it "the antagonism of capital accumulation" and he cites his '']'', (Chapter 2, Section 1) to explain this phenomenon in relation with ].<ref>'']'', Chapter 25</ref> One could add that the larger the wealth of society, the more people it can support who do not work. However, as Marx develops the argument further, it also becomes clear that, depending on the state of the economy, the reserve army of labour will either expand or contract, alternately being absorbed or expelled from the employed workforce.
{{Main|Profit motive}}
The ], in the theory of capitalism, is the desire to earn income in the form of profit. Stated differently, the reason for a business's existence is to turn a profit.<ref>
Compare:
{{cite book
| last1 = Duska
| first1 = Ronald F.
| year = 1997
| chapter = The Why's of Business Revisited
| title = Contemporary Reflections on Business Ethics
| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=dANmdJHsqu0C
| series = Issues in Business Ethics
| volume = 23
| location = Dordrecht
| publisher = Springer Science & Business Media
| publication-date = 2007
| page = 41
| isbn = 978-1-4020-4984-2
| access-date = 8 July 2019
| quote = In microeconomics courses, profit maximization is frequently given as the goal of the firm. ... In microeconomics, profit maximization functions largely as a theoretical goal, with economists using it to prove how firms behave rationally to increase profit. Unfortunately, it ignores many real-world complexities.
}}
</ref> The profit motive functions according to ], or the theory that individuals tend to pursue what is in their own best interests. Accordingly, businesses seek to benefit themselves and/or their shareholders by maximizing profit.


In capitalist theoretics, the profit motive is said to ensure that resources are being allocated efficiently. For instance, ] ] explains: "If there is no profit in making an article, it is a sign that the labor and capital devoted to its production are misdirected: the value of the resources that must be used up in making the article is greater than the value of the article itself".<ref>Hazlitt, Henry. "The Function of Profits". ''Economics in One Lesson''. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. Web. 22 April 2013.</ref>
{{Quotation|Taking them as a whole, the general movements of ] are exclusively regulated by the expansion and contraction of the industrial reserve army, and these again correspond to the periodic changes of the industrial cycle. They are, therefore, not determined by the variations of the absolute number of the working population, but by the varying proportions in which the working-class is divided into active and reserve army, by the increase or diminution in the relative amount of the surplus-population, by the extent to which it is now absorbed, now set free.}}
In recent years, there has been growing research on the concept of "the ]", to describe a growing reliance on temporary, part-time workers with precarious status, who share aspects of the proletariat and the reserve army of labor.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Choonara|first=Esme|title=Is there a precariat?|journal=Socialist Review|date=October 2011|url=http://www.socialistreview.org.uk/article.php?articlenumber=11781}}</ref> Precarious workers do work part-time or full-time in temporary jobs, but they cannot really earn enough to live on, and depend partly on friends or family, or on state benefits, to survive. Typically they do not become truly "unemployed", but they don't have a stable job to go to either.<ref>Jan Breman, "A bogus concept?", ''New Left Review'' 84, November–December 2013, pp. 130–38.</ref> The rise of "the precariat" has been attributed to the emergence of global ].<ref>Lorna Fox O'Mahony, David O'Mahony and Robin Hickey (eds.), (London, ], 2014), {{ISBN|0-415-74061-4}} .</ref>


Socialist theorists note that, unlike mercantilists, capitalists accumulate their profits while expecting their profit rates to remain the same. This causes problems as earnings in the rest of society do not increase in the same proportion.<ref>"What is capitalism" ''Australian Socialist'' https://search.informit.org/doi/10.3316/informit.818838886883514</ref>
Although non-employed people who are unable or uninterested in performing legal paid work are not considered among the "unemployed", the concept of "conjunctural unemployment" is used in economics nowadays.<ref>{{cite book |first=Ben |last=Fine |title=Labour Market Theory: A Constructive Reassessment |publisher=Routledge |location=London |year=1998 |isbn=0-415-16676-4 }}</ref> Economists often distinguish between short-term "frictional" or "cyclical" unemployment, and longer-term "structural unemployment". Sometimes there is a short-term mismatch between the demand and supply of labour, at other times there is much less total demand for labour than supply for a long-time. If no possibility for getting a job at all in the foreseeable future exists, many younger people decide to migrate or emigrate to a place where they can find work.


=== Private property ===
==== Composition of the relative surplus population ====
{{Main|Private property}}
Marx discusses the army of labor and the reserve army in Capital, Ch. 25, Section IV. The Army of Labor consists in those working-class people employed in average or better than average jobs. Not every one in the working class gets one of these jobs. There are then four other categories where members of the working class might find themselves: the "stagnant pool", the ''floating reserves'', the ''latent reserve,'' and pauperdom. Finally, people may leave the army and the reserve army by turning to criminality, and Marx refers to such people as "lumpenproletariat".<ref>Duggan, Marie Christine (2013) "Reserve Army of Labor and Migration" in the ''Encyclopedia of Global Human Migration'', edited by E. Ness, Wiley Publishers. http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/9781444351071.wbeghm451/abstract</ref>
The relationship between the ], its formal mechanisms, and capitalist societies has been debated in many fields of social and political theory, with active discussion since the 19th century. ] is a contemporary Peruvian economist who has argued that an important characteristic of capitalism is the functioning state protection of property rights in a formal property system where ownership and transactions are clearly recorded.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/03/desoto.htm|title=The mystery of capital|author=Hernando de Soto|access-date=26 February 2008|archive-date=8 February 2008|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080208180121/http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/03/desoto.htm|url-status=live}}</ref>
* The stagnant part consists of marginalised people with "extremely irregular employment". Stagnant pool jobs are characterized by below average pay, dangerous working conditions, they may be temporary. Those caught in the stagnant pool have jobs, so the modern definition of the employed would include both the army of labor plus the stagnant pool. However, they are constantly on the lookout for something better.


According to de Soto, this is the process by which physical assets are transformed into capital, which in turn may be used in many more ways and much more efficiently in the market economy. A number of Marxian economists have argued that the ]s in England and similar legislation elsewhere were an integral part of capitalist ] and that specific legal frameworks of private land ownership have been integral to the development of capitalism.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch27.htm|title=Capital, v. 1. Part VIII: primitive accumulation|author=Karl Marx|access-date=26 February 2008|archive-date=3 March 2008|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080303162047/http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch27.htm|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |author=N.F.R. Crafts |title=Enclosure and labor supply revisited |journal=Explorations in Economic History |issue=2 |date=April 1978 |pages=172–183 |doi=10.1016/0014-4983(78)90019-0 |volume=15}}</ref>
The modern unemployed would refer primarily to the floating reserve, people who used to have good jobs, but are now out of work. They certainly hope that their unemployment is temporary ("conjunctural unemployment"), but they are well aware that they could fall into the stagnant pool or the pauper class.
* The latent part consists of that segment of the population not yet fully integrated into capitalist production. In Marx' day, he was referring to people living off of subsistence agriculture who were looking for monetary employment in industry. In modern times, people coming from slums in developing countries where they survive largely by non-monetary means, to developed cities where they work for pay might form the latent. Housewives who move from unpaid to paid employment for a business could also form a part of the latent reserve. They are not unemployed, because they are not necessarily actively looking for a job; but if capital needs extra workers, it can pull them out of the latent reserve. In this sense, the latent forms a reservoir of potential workers for industries.
* Pauperdom is where one might end up. The homeless is the modern term for paupers. Marx calls them people who cannot adapt to capital's never ending change. For Karl Marx, "the sphere of pauperism", including those still able to work, orphans and pauper children, and the "demoralised and ragged" or "unable to work".


Private property rights are not absolute, as in many countries the state has the power to seize private property, typically for public use, under the powers of ].
=== As a mode of production ===
{{Further information|Mode of production}}
In Karl Marx' critique of political economy and subsequent Marxian analyses, the capitalist mode of production refers to the systems of organising production and distribution within capitalist ]. Private money-making in various forms (renting, banking, merchant trade, production for profit, etc.) preceded the development of the capitalist mode of production as such. The capitalist mode of production proper, based on wage-labour and private ownership of the means of production, and on industrial technology, began to grow rapidly in Western Europe from the ], later extending to most of the world.{{citation needed|date=June 2015}}


=== Market competition ===
The term capitalist mode of production is defined by ] of the ], extraction of ] by the owning class for the purpose of ], ], and, at least as far as ] are concerned, being ].<ref>{{cite web | url=http://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capitalism | title=Capitalism. | publisher=marxists.org | accessdate=8 July 2011 | author=Encyclopedia of Marxism at marxism.org}}</ref>
{{Main|Competition (economics)}}
In capitalist economics, market competition is the rivalry among sellers trying to achieve such goals as increasing profits, market share and sales volume by varying the elements of the ]: price, product, distribution and promotion. Merriam-Webster defines competition in business as "the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favourable terms".<ref>{{cite web |url=http://m-w.com/dictionary/competition |title=Definition of COMPETITION |access-date=24 March 2015 |archive-date=4 July 2008 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20080704114809/http://m-w.com/dictionary/competition |url-status=dead}}</ref> It was described by ] in '']'' (1776) and later economists as allocating productive ]s to their most highly valued uses<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |first=George J. |last=Stigler |author-link=George J. Stigler |date=2008 |title=competition |dictionary=] |edition=2nd |url=http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000261&q=competition&topicid=&result_number=6 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150215032134/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C000261&q=competition&topicid=&result_number=6 |archive-date=15 February 2015}}</ref> and encouraging ]. Smith and other ]s before ] were referring to price and non-price rivalry among producers to sell their goods on best terms by bidding of buyers, not necessarily to a large number of sellers nor to a market in final ].<ref>{{cite encyclopedia |first=Mark |last=Blaug |author-link=Mark Blaug |date=2008 |title=Invisible hand |dictionary=] |edition=2nd |volume=4 |page=565 |url=http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_I000220&edition=current&q=Invisible%20hand&topicid=&result_number=1 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130605204024/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_I000220&edition=current&q=Invisible%20hand&topicid=&result_number=1 |archive-date=5 June 2013}}</ref> Competition is widespread throughout the ]. It is a condition where "buyers tend to compete with other buyers, and sellers tend to compete with other sellers".<ref name=ewot2014 /><!-- p. 102 --> In offering goods for exchange, buyers competitively bid to purchase specific quantities of specific goods which are available, or might be available if sellers were to choose to offer such goods. Similarly, sellers bid against other sellers in offering goods on the market, competing for the attention and exchange resources of buyers. Competition results from ], as it is not possible to satisfy all conceivable human wants, and occurs as people try to meet the criteria being used to determine allocation.<ref name=ewot2014>{{cite book |last1=Heyne |first1=Paul |last2=Boettke |first2=Peter J. |last3=Prychitko |first3=David L. |title=The Economic Way of Thinking |date=2014 |publisher=Pearson |isbn=978-0-13-299129-2 |pages=102–106 |edition=13th}}<!--|access-date=24 December 2014 --></ref>{{rp|105}}


In the works of Adam Smith, the idea of capitalism is made possible through competition which creates growth. Although capitalism had not entered mainstream economics at the time of Smith, it is vital to the construction of his ideal society. One of the foundational blocks of capitalism is competition. Smith believed that a prosperous society is one where "everyone should be free to enter and leave the market and change trades as often as he pleases."<ref name="W.W. Norton">{{cite book |last1=Warsh |first1=David |title=Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations |date=2007 |publisher=] |page=42}}</ref> He believed that the freedom to act in one's self-interest is essential for the success of a capitalist society. In response to the idea that if all participants focus on their own goals, society's well-being will be water under the bridge, Smith maintains that despite the concerns of intellectuals, "global trends will hardly be altered if they refrain from pursuing their personal ends."<ref>{{cite book |last1=Lippit |first1=Victor |title=Capitalism |date=2005 |publisher=] |location=ProQuest |page=2}}</ref> He insisted that the actions of a few participants cannot alter the course of society. Instead, Smith maintained that they should focus on personal progress instead and that this will result in overall growth to the whole.
Capitalism in the form of money-making activity has existed in the shape of merchants and money-lenders who acted as intermediaries between consumers and producers engaging in ] (hence the reference to "]") since the beginnings of civilisation. What is specific about the “capitalist mode of production” is that most of the inputs and outputs of ] are supplied through the market (i.e. they are commodities) and essentially all production is in this mode.<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54" /> For example, in flourishing Feudalism, most or all of the factors of production including labour are owned by the feudal ruling class outright and the products may also be consumed without a market of any kind, it is production for use within the feudal social unit and for limited trade.<ref name=ch32/> This has the important consequence that the whole organisation of the production process is ''reshaped and re-organised'' to conform with economic ] by capitalism, which is expressed in price relationships between inputs and outputs (wages, non-labour factor costs, sales, profits) rather than the larger rational context faced by society overall. That is, the whole process is organised and re-shaped in order to conform to “commercial logic”. Essentially, capital accumulation comes to define economic rationality in capitalist production.<ref name=xxx31>{{cite web|url=http://www.dsp.org.au/node/31|title=The contradictions of capitalism – Democratic Socialist Perspective|publisher=dsp.org.au}}</ref>


Competition between participants, "who are all endeavoring to justle one another out of employment, obliges every man to endeavor to execute his work" through competition towards growth.<ref name="W.W. Norton"/>
A society, region or ] is capitalist if the predominant source of incomes and products being distributed is capitalist activity, but even so this does not yet mean necessarily that the capitalist mode of production is dominant in that society.


=== Economic growth ===
== Wage labour <!--'Wage system' redirects here-->==
{{further|Economic growth}}
{{Main article|Wage labour}}
{{expand section|date=January 2021}}
] amidst heavy steel ]s (Kinex Bearings, ], ], c. 1995–2000)]]
] refers to the sale of ] under a formal or informal ] to an ].<ref>{{Harvnb|Steinfeld|2009|p=3}}: "All labor contracts were/are designed legally to bind a worker in one way or another to fulfill the labor obligations the worker has undertaken. That is one of the principal purposes of labor contracts."</ref> These transactions usually occur in a ] where ]s are market determined.<ref>{{Harvnb|Deakin|Wilkinson|2005}}.<br />{{Harvnb|Marx|1990|p=1005}}, defines wage labour succinctly as "the labour of the worker who sells his own labour-power."</ref> Individuals who possess and supply financial capital or labor to productive ventures often become owners, either jointly (as ]s) or individually. In Marxist economics these owners of the means of production and suppliers of capital are generally called capitalists. The description of the role of the ''capitalist'' has shifted, first referring to a useless intermediary between producers to an employer of producers, and eventually came to refer to owners of the means of production.<ref name="Williams 1983 51" /> ] includes all physical and mental human resources, including entrepreneurial capacity and management skills, which are needed to produce products and services. ] is the act of making goods or services by applying ].<ref>Christopher T. S. Ragan and Richard G. Lipsey. ''Microeconomics''. Twelfth Canadian Edition ed. Toronto, Pearson Education Canada, 2008. Print.</ref><ref>Robbins, Richard H. ''Global problems and the culture of capitalism''. Boston: Allyn & Bacon, 2007. Print.</ref>


] is a characteristic tendency of capitalist economies.<ref name=joff>{{cite journal|title=The root cause of economic growth under capitalism |journal=] |year=2011 |issue=5 |pages=873–896 |first=Michael |last=Joff |volume=35 |quote=The tendency for capitalist economies to grow is one of their most characteristic properties. |doi=10.1093/cje/beq054}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Baumol |first1=William J. |title=The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism |date=2004 |publisher=] |location=Princeton |isbn=9780691116303}}</ref> However, capitalist economies may experience fluctuations in growth that cannot be accounted for by demographic or technological changes. These fluctuations, which involve sustained periods of economic growth and recession, are referred to as business cycles in macroeconomics. Economic growth is measured as growth in investment, economic output, and economic consumption per capita. Changes in hours of employment on their own are not considered as a factor of economic growth.<ref name = "HP"/>
Critics of the capitalist mode of production see wage labour as a major, if not defining, aspect of hierarchical industrial systems. Most opponents of the institution support ] and ] as alternatives to both wage labour and to capitalism. While most opponents of the wage system<!--boldface per WP:R#PLA--> blame the capitalist owners of the means of production for its existence, most ] and other ] also hold the state as equally responsible as it exists as a tool utilised by capitalists to subsidise themselves and protect the institution of ]. As some opponents of wage labour take influence from Marxist propositions, many are opposed to ], but maintain respect for ].


=== Types === === As a mode of production ===
{{further|Mode of production}}
The most common form of wage labour currently is ordinary direct, or "full-time", employment in which a free worker sells his or her labour for an indeterminate time (from a few years to the entire career of the worker), in return for a money-wage or salary and a continuing relationship with the employer which it does not in general offer contractors or other irregular staff. However, wage labour takes many other forms, and explicit as opposed to implicit (i.e. conditioned by local labour and tax law) contracts are not uncommon. Economic history shows a great variety of ways in which labour is traded and exchanged. The differences show up in the form of:
The capitalist mode of production refers to the systems of organising production and distribution within capitalist ]. Private money-making in various forms (renting, banking, merchant trade, production for profit and so on) preceded the development of the capitalist mode of production as such.
* Employment status: a worker could be employed full-time, part-time, or on a casual basis. He or she could be employed for example temporarily for a specific project only, or on a permanent basis. Part-time wage labour could combine with part-time ]. The worker could be employed also as an ].
* Civil (legal) status: the worker could for example be a free citizen, an ]er, the subject of ] (including some prison or army labour); a worker could be assigned by the political authorities to a task, they could be a ] or a ] bound to the land who is hired out part of the time. So the labour might be performed on a more or less voluntary basis, or on a more or less involuntary basis, in which there are many gradations.
* Method of payment (remuneration or ]). The work done could be paid "in cash" (a money-wage) or "in kind" (through receiving goods and/or services), or in the form of "]" where the wage is directly dependent on how much the worker produces. In some cases, the worker might be paid in the form of credit used to buy goods and services, or in the form of ] or ] in an enterprise.
* Method of hiring: the worker might engage in a labour-contract on his or her own initiative, or he or she might hire out their labour as part of a group. But he or she may also hire out their labour via an intermediary (such as an employment agency) to a third party. In this case, he or she is paid by the intermediary, but works for a third party which pays the intermediary. In some cases, labour is ] several times, with several intermediaries. Another possibility is that the worker is assigned or posted to a job by a political authority, or that an agency hires out a worker to an enterprise ''together'' with ].


The term capitalist mode of production is defined by ] of the ], extraction of ] by the owning class for the purpose of ], ] and, at least as far as ] are concerned, being ].<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capitalism |title=Capitalism |publisher=] |access-date=8 July 2011 |author=Encyclopedia of Marxism at marxism.org |archive-date=7 May 2019 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190507154837/https://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capitalism |url-status=live}}</ref>
=== Comparison to slavery ===
{{Main article|Wage slavery}}
] escort strikebreakers in Buchtel, Ohio, 1884]]
Wage labour has long been compared to slavery.<ref name="English Working Class p. 599">{{Harvnb|Thompson|1966|p=599}}.</ref><ref name="English Working Class p. 912">{{Harvnb|Thompson|1966|p=912}}.</ref><ref name="Geoffrey Ostergaard p. 133">{{Harvnb|Ostergaard|1997|p=133}}.</ref><ref name="Shop Floor p. 37">{{Harvnb|Lazonick|1990|p=37}}.</ref> As a result, the phrase ] is often utilised as a pejorative for wage labour.<ref>{{Harvnb|Hallgrimsdottir|Benoit|2007}}; {{Harvnb|Roediger|2007a}}.<br />The term is not without its critics, as {{Harvnb|Roediger|2007b|p=247}}, notes: "he challenge to loose connections of wage (or white) slavery to chattel slavery was led by ] and other Black, often fugitive, abolitionists. Their challenge was mercilessly concrete. Douglass, who tried out speeches in work places before giving them in halls, was far from unable to speak to or hear white workers, but he and ] did challenge metaphors regarding white slavery sharply. They noted, for example, that their escapes from slavery had left job openings and wondered if any white workers wanted to take the jobs."</ref> Similarly, advocates of slavery looked upon the "comparative evils of Slave Society and of Free Society, of slavery to human Masters and slavery to Capital",<ref name="Fitzhugh 1857 xvi">{{Harvnb|Fitzhugh|1857|p=}}</ref> and proceeded to argue that wage slavery was actually ''worse'' than ].<ref>{{Harvnb|Carsel|1940}}.</ref> Slavery apologists like ] contended that workers only accepted wage labour with the passage of time, as they became "familiarised and inattentive to the infected social atmosphere they continually inhale".<ref name="Fitzhugh 1857 xvi" /> Scholars have debated the exact relationship between wage labor, slavery, and capitalism at length, especially for the antebellum United States.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://networks.h-net.org/node/11465/pages/76870/capitalism-and-slavery-united-states-topical-guide|title=Capitalism and Slavery in the United States (Topical Guide) – H-Slavery – H-Net|publisher=}}</ref>


Capitalism in the form of money-making activity has existed in the shape of merchants and money-lenders who acted as intermediaries between consumers and producers engaging in ] (hence the reference to "]") since the beginnings of civilisation. What is specific about the "capitalist mode of production" is that most of the inputs and outputs of production are supplied through the market (i.e. they are commodities) and essentially all production is in this mode.<ref name="Modern Economics 1986, p. 54" /> By contrast, in flourishing feudalism most or all of the factors of production, including labor, are owned by the feudal ruling class outright and the products may also be consumed without a market of any kind, it is production for use within the feudal social unit and for limited trade.<ref name=ch32 /> This has the important consequence that, under capitalism, the whole organisation of the production process is reshaped and re-organised to conform with economic ] by capitalism, which is expressed in price relationships between inputs and outputs (wages, non-labor factor costs, sales and profits) rather than the larger rational context faced by society overall—that is, the whole process is organised and re-shaped in order to conform to "commercial logic". Essentially, capital accumulation comes to define economic rationality in capitalist production.<ref name=xxx31>{{cite web|url=http://www.dsp.org.au/node/31 |title=The contradictions of capitalism – Democratic Socialist Perspective |publisher=dsp.org.au |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150406094810/http://www.dsp.org.au/node/31 |archive-date=6 April 2015}}</ref>
Similarities between wage labour and slavery were noted as early as ] in Ancient Rome.<ref>"...vulgar are the means of livelihood of all hired workmen whom we pay for mere ], not for artistic skill; for in their case the very wage they receive is a pledge of their slavery." – ] </ref> With the advent of the ], thinkers such as ] and ] elaborated the comparison between wage labour and slavery in the context of a critique of societal property not intended for active personal use,<ref>{{Harvnb|Proudhon|1890}}.</ref><ref name="Marx 1863 c7">{{Harvnb|Marx|1969|loc=}}</ref> while ]s emphasised the ] brought about by machines. Before the ], Southern defenders of ] slavery invoked the concept of wage slavery to favorably compare the condition of their slaves to workers in the North.<ref>{{Harvnb|Foner|1995|p=xix}}.</ref><ref>{{Harvnb|Jensen|2002}}.</ref> The United States abolished slavery during the Civil War, but labor union activists found the metaphor useful. According to ], in the ] "references abounded in the labor press, and it is hard to find a speech by a labour leader without the phrase".<ref>{{cite book|author=Lawrence B. Glickman|title=A Living Wage: American Workers and the Making of Consumer Society|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=uaZeBhl2QLYC&pg=PA19|year=1999|publisher=Cornell UP|page=19}}</ref>


A society, region or ] is capitalist if the predominant source of incomes and products being distributed is capitalist activity, but even so this does not yet mean necessarily that the capitalist mode of production is dominant in that society.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Capitalism|url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/capitalism.asp|access-date=14 February 2022|website=Investopedia|language=en}}</ref>
{{Quote box
|quote=The slave, together with his labour-power, was sold to his owner once for all.... The labourer, on the other hand, sells his very self, and that by fractions.... He to the capitalist class; and it is for him ... to find a buyer in this capitalist class.<ref>{{Harvnb|Marx|1847|loc=}}</ref>|source=]|align=left|width=40%|fontsize=91%|bgcolor=AliceBlue|tstyle=text-align: left;|qalign=right|qstyle=text-align: left;|quoted=yes|salign=right|sstyle=text-align: right;}}
According to ], analysis of the psychological implications of wage slavery goes back to the ] era. In his 1791 book ''On the Limits of State Action'', classical ] thinker ] explained how "whatever does not spring from a man's free choice, or is only the result of instruction and guidance, does not enter into his very nature; he does not perform it with truly human energies, but merely with mechanical exactness" and so when the labourer works under external control, "we may admire what he does, but we despise what he is".<ref>{{Harvnb|Chomsky|1993|p=}}</ref> Both the ] and ]s have been found useful in the psychological study of wage-based workplace relations.<ref>{{Harvnb|Thye|Lawler|2006}}.</ref> Additionally, as per anthropologist ], the earliest wage labour contracts we know about were in fact contracts for the rental of chattel slaves (usually the owner would receive a share of the money, and the slave, another, with which to maintain his or her living expenses.) Such arrangements, according to Graeber, were quite common in New World slavery as well, whether in the United States or Brazil.<ref>{{Harvnb|Graeber|2004|p=}}</ref> ] argued in '']'' that most of the techniques of human organisation employed on factory workers during the industrial revolution were first developed on slave plantations.<ref>{{Harvnb|Graeber|2007|p=106}}.</ref>


] rely on the nation they are in to provide some goods or services, while the free market produces and maintains the rest.<ref name=":1" />
Laura Del Col, West Virginia University</ref>]]
Some anti-capitalist thinkers claim that the ] maintain wage ] and a divided working class through their influence over the media and entertainment industry,<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.democracynow.org/article.pl?sid=07/10/19/144225 |title=Democracy Now |date=19 October 2007 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20071113204609/http://www.democracynow.org/article.pl?sid=07%2F10%2F19%2F144225 |archivedate=13 November 2007 |df=dmy-all }}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.chomsky.info/interviews/1992----02.htm |title=Interview |year=1992 |author=Chomsky, Noam |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20060721164116/http://www.chomsky.info/interviews/1992----02.htm |archivedate=21 July 2006 |df=dmy-all }}</ref> educational institutions, unjust laws, nationalist and corporate ], pressures and incentives to internalise values serviceable to the power structure, ] violence, fear of ]<ref>{{cite web |url=http://question-everything.mahost.org/Socio-Politics/thoughtcontrol.html |title=Thought Control |work=Socio-Politics |publisher=Question Everything}}</ref> and a historical legacy of exploitation and profit accumulation/transfer under prior systems, which shaped the development of economic theory:


=== Role of government ===
] noted that employers often conspire together to keep wages low:<ref> {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20091001132821/http://www.adamsmith.org/smith/won-b5-c1-article-2-ss3.htm |date=1 October 2009 }}</ref>
Government agencies regulate the standards of service in many industries, such as airlines and broadcasting, as well as financing a wide range of programs. In addition, the government regulates the flow of capital and uses financial tools such as the interest rate to control such factors as inflation and unemployment.<ref>"Capitalism." World Book Encyclopedia. 1988. p. 194.</ref>
{{quote|The interest of the dealers... in any particular branch of trade or manufactures, is always in some respects different from, and even opposite to, that of the public… have generally an interest to deceive and even to oppress the public… We rarely hear, it has been said, of the combinations of masters, though frequently of those of workmen. But whoever imagines, upon this account, that masters rarely combine, is as ignorant of the world as of the subject. Masters are always and everywhere in a sort of tacit, but constant and uniform combination, not to raise the wages of labor above their actual rate… It is not, however, difficult to foresee which of the two parties must, upon all ordinary occasions, have the advantage in the dispute, and force the other into a compliance with their terms.}}

] made the statement "...the citizens must not live a mechanic or a mercantile life (for such a life is ignoble and inimical to virtue), nor yet must those who are to be citizens in the best state be tillers of the soil (for leisure is needed both for the development of virtue and for active participation in politics)",<ref>Aristotle, '']'' 1328b–1329a, H. Rackham trans.</ref> often paraphrased as "all paid jobs absorb and degrade the mind."<ref name="quotationspage.com">{{cite web|url=http://www.quotationspage.com/quote/1097.html|title=The Quotations Page: Quote from Aristotle|publisher=}}</ref> ] wrote in 44 BC that "…vulgar are the means of livelihood of all hired workmen whom we pay for mere manual labour, not for artistic skill; for in their case the very wage they receive is a pledge of their slavery".<ref>] Liber I XI.II</ref>
Somewhat similar criticisms have also been expressed by some proponents of ], like ],<ref>{{Harvnb|George|1981|loc=}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://globetrotter.berkeley.edu/people2/Chomsky/chomsky-con2.html|title=Conversation with Noam Chomsky, p. 2 of 5|publisher=}}</ref> ] and ],<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.ssa.gov/history/paine4.html|title=Social Security History|publisher=}}</ref> as well as the ] school of thought within the ].

To ] and ] thinkers like ] and ], wage slavery was a ] in place due to the existence of ] and the ]. This class situation rested primarily on:
# the existence of property not intended for active use,
# the concentration of ownership in few hands,
# the lack of direct access by workers to the ] and consumption goods
# the perpetuation of a ].

For Marxists, labour-as-commodity, which is how they regard wage labour,<ref>{{Harvnb|Marx|1990|p=1006}}: "abour-power, a commodity sold by the worker himself."</ref> provides a fundamental point of attack against capitalism.<ref>Another one, of course, being the capitalists' theft from workers via ].</ref> "It can be persuasively argued", noted one concerned philosopher, "that the conception of the worker's labour as a commodity confirms Marx's stigmatization of the wage system of private capitalism as 'wage-slavery;' that is, as an instrument of the capitalist's for reducing the worker's condition to that of a slave, if not below it."<ref>{{Harvnb|Nelson|1995|p=158}}. This marxist objection is what motivated Nelson's essay, which argues that labour is not, in fact, a commodity.</ref> That this objection is fundamental follows immediately from Marx's conclusion that wage labour is the very foundation of capitalism: "Without a ''class dependent on wages'', the moment individuals confront each other as free persons, there can be no production of surplus value; without the production of surplus-value there can be no capitalist production, and hence no capital and no capitalist!"<ref>{{Harvnb|Marx|1990|p=1005}}. Emphasis in the original. <br />See also p.&nbsp;716: "he capitalist produces the worker as a wage-labourer. This incessant reproduction, this perpetuation of the worker, is the absolutely necessary condition for capitalist production."</ref>

== Systemic weaknesses ==
=== Externalities ===
{{Main article|Externality|Commons}}
Market failure occurs when an ] is present and a market will often either under-produce a product with a positive externalisation or overproduce a product that generates a negative externalisation. Air pollution, for instance, is a negative externalisation that cannot be easily incorporated into markets as the world's air is not owned and then sold for use to polluters. So, too much pollution could be emitted and people not involved in the production pay the cost of the pollution instead of the firm that initially emitted the air pollution. Critics of market failure theory, like ], ], and ] argue that government programs and policies also fall short of absolute perfection. While all nations currently have some kind of market regulations, the desirable degree of regulation is disputed.{{citation needed|date=February 2016}}

=== Anti-competitive practices ===
{{Main article|Anti-competitive practices}}
{{Further information|Competition law}}
The doctrine of free competition is essential to the functioning of a capitalist economy and as such anti-competitive behaviour in the market poses a crucial weakness in capitalist economics. Issues such as ] on the part of corporations and ] pose problems to capitalist economies.

== Capital accumulation ==
{{Main article|Capital accumulation}}
{{Further information|Money}}
The ] refers to the process of "making money", or growing an initial sum of money through investment in production. Capitalism is based around the accumulation of capital, whereby ] is invested in order to make a profit and then reinvested into further production in a continuous process of accumulation. In Marxian economic theory, this dynamic is called the ]. Capital accumulation forms the basis of capitalism, where economic activity is structured around the accumulation of ], defined as investment in order to realize a financial profit.<ref name="Economist definition">{{cite news | title = Economics A–Z: ''Capital'' | url = http://www.economist.com/economics-a-to-z/c#node-21529870 | website = ] | accessdate = 25 March 2015 }}</ref> In this context, "capital" is defined as money or a financial asset invested for the purpose of making more money (whether in the form of profit, rent, interest, royalties, capital gain or some other kind of return).<ref name="MIA definition">{{cite web | title = Encyclopedia of Marxism – Glossary of terms: ''Capital'' | url = http://marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capital | website = ] | accessdate = 25 March 2015 }}</ref>

In ], ] and ], capital accumulation is often equated with ] of profit income or savings, especially in ] capital goods. The concentration and centralisation of capital are two of the results of such accumulation. In modern ] and ] the phrase '']'' is often used in preference to "accumulation", though the ] (UNCTAD) refers nowadays to "accumulation". The phrase {{clarify|date=April 2016}} is occasionally used in ].

=== Background ===
{{Unreferenced section|date=October 2015}}
Accumulation can be measured as the monetary value of investments, the amount of income that is reinvested, or as the change in the value of assets owned (the increase in the value of the capital stock). Using company ]s, ] data and direct ] as a basis, government statisticians estimate total investments and assets for the purpose of ], national ] and ] statistics. Usually the ] and the ] provide interpretations and analysis of this data. Standard indicators include ], ], ], household asset wealth, and ].

Organisations such as the ], the UNCTAD, the ], the ], and the ] used national investment data to estimate world trends. The ], ] and the Japan Statistical Office provide data on the United States, Europe and Japan respectively. Other useful sources of investment information are business magazines such as ''], ], ], ]'', etc., and various corporate "]" organisations and ] publications. A reputable scientific journal is the ''Review of Income & Wealth''. In the case of the United States, the "Analytical Perspectives" document (an annex to the yearly budget) provides useful wealth and capital estimates applying to the whole country.

In ]' economic theory, capital accumulation refers to the operation whereby profits are reinvested increasing the total quantity of capital. Capital is viewed by Marx as expanding value, that is, in other terms, as a sum of capital, usually expressed in money, that is transformed through human labor into a larger value, extracted as profits and expressed as money. Here, capital is defined essentially as economic or commercial asset ] in search of additional value or ]. This requires property relations which enable objects of value to be appropriated and owned, and trading rights to be established. Capital accumulation has a double origin, namely in trade and in ], both of a legal or illegal kind. The reason is that a stock of capital can be increased through a process of exchange or "trading up" but also through directly taking an asset or resource from someone else, without compensation. ] calls this ].

The continuation and progress of capital accumulation depends on the removal of obstacles to the expansion of trade, and this has historically often been a violent process. As markets expand, more and more new opportunities develop for accumulating capital, because more and more types of goods and services can be traded in. But capital accumulation may also confront resistance, when people refuse to sell, or refuse to buy (for example a ] by investors or workers, or ]).

=== Concentration and centralisation ===
According to Marx, capital has the tendency for concentration and centralization in the hands of the wealthy. Marx explains: "It is concentration of capitals already formed, destruction of their individual independence, expropriation of capitalist by capitalist, transformation of many small into few large capitals. ... Capital grows in one place to a huge mass in a single hand, because it has in another place been lost by many. ... The battle of competition is fought by cheapening of commodities. The cheapness of commodities demands, ''caeteris paribus'', on the productiveness of labour, and this again on the scale of production. Therefore, the larger capitals beat the smaller. It will further be remembered that, with the development of the capitalist mode of production, there is an increase in the minimum amount of individual capital necessary to carry on a business under its normal conditions. The smaller capitals, therefore, crowd into spheres of production which Modern Industry has only sporadically or incompletely got hold of. Here competition rages ... It always ends in the ruin of many small capitalists, whose capitals partly pass into the hands of their conquerors, partly vanish."<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch25.htm|title=Economic Manuscripts: Capital Vol. I – Chapter Twenty-Five|first=Karl|last=Marx|publisher=}}</ref>

=== The rate of accumulation ===
{{Unreferenced section|date=October 2015}}
In ], the ''rate of accumulation'' is defined as (1) the value of the real net increase in the ] of capital in an accounting period, (2) the proportion of realised ] or profit-income which is reinvested, rather than consumed. This rate can be expressed by means of various ratios between the original capital outlay, the realised turnover, surplus-value or profit and reinvestments (see, e.g., the writings of the economist ]).

Other things being equal, the greater the amount of profit-income that is disbursed as personal earnings and used for consumptive purposes, the lower the savings rate and the lower the rate of accumulation is likely to be. However, earnings spent on consumption can also stimulate market demand and higher investment. This is the cause of endless controversies in economic theory about "how much to spend, and how much to save".

In a boom period of capitalism, the growth of investments is cumulative, i.e. one investment leads to another, leading to a constantly expanding market, an expanding ], and an increase in the standard of living for the majority of the people.

In a stagnating, decadent capitalism, the accumulation process is increasingly oriented towards investment on military and security forces, real estate, financial speculation, and luxury consumption. In that case, income from ] production will decline in favour of interest, rent and tax income, with as a corollary an increase in the level of permanent unemployment. The more capital one owns, the more capital one can also borrow. The inverse is also true, and this is one factor in the widening gap between the rich and the poor.

] emphasised that the rhythm of capital accumulation and growth depended critically on (1) the division of a society's social product between "]" and "]", and (2) the division of the surplus product between ] and ]. In turn, this allocation pattern reflected the outcome of ] among capitalists, competition between capitalists and workers, and competition between workers. The pattern of capital accumulation can therefore never be simply explained by commercial factors, it also involved social factors and ] relationships.

=== The circuit of capital accumulation from production ===
{{Unreferenced section|date=October 2015}}
Strictly speaking, capital has accumulated only when realised ] income has been ''reinvested'' in capital assets. But the process of capital accumulation in ] has, as suggested in the first volume of Marx' '']'', at least seven distinct but linked moments:
* The initial investment of ] (which could be borrowed capital) in ] and ].
* The command over ] and its appropriation.
* The ] (increase in value) of capital through production of new outputs.
* The appropriation of the new output produced by employees, containing the added value.
* The realisation of ] through output sales.
* The appropriation of realised surplus-value as (profit) income after deduction of costs.
* The reinvestment of profit income in production.

All of these moments do not refer simply to an "economic" or commercial process. Rather, they assume the existence of legal, social, cultural and economic power conditions, without which creation, distribution and circulation of the new wealth could not occur. This becomes especially clear when the attempt is made to create a market where none exists, or where people refuse to trade.

=== Simple and expanded reproduction ===
{{Unreferenced section|date=October 2015}}
In volume 2 of ''Das Kapital'', Marx continues the story and shows that, with the aid of bank ], capital in search of growth can more or less smoothly mutate from one form to another, alternately taking the form of money capital (liquid deposits, securities, etc.), commodity capital (tradable products, real estate etc.), or production capital (] and labor power).

His discussion of the simple and expanded ] of the conditions of production offers a more sophisticated model of the parameters of the accumulation process as a whole. At simple reproduction, a sufficient amount is produced to sustain society at the given ]; the stock of capital stays constant. At expanded reproduction, ''more'' product-value is produced than is necessary to sustain society at a given living standard (a ]); the additional product-value is available for investments which enlarge the scale and variety of production.

The bourgeois claim there is no ] according to which capital is necessarily re-invested in the expansion of production, that such depends on anticipated profitability, market expectations and perceptions of investment risk. Such statements only explain the subjective experiences of investors and ignore the objective realities which would influence such opinions. As Marx states in Vol. 2, simple reproduction only exists if the variable and surplus capital realised by Dept. 1{{snd}}producers of means of production{{snd}}exactly equals that of the constant capital of Dept. 2, producers of articles of consumption (p.&nbsp;524). Such equilibrium rests on various assumptions, such as a constant labor supply (no population growth). Accumulation does not imply a necessary change in total magnitude of value produced but can simply refer to a change in the composition of an industry (p.&nbsp;514).

] introduced the additional concept of ''contracted economic reproduction'', i.e. reduced accumulation where business operating at a loss outnumbers growing business, or economic reproduction on a decreasing scale, for example due to wars, natural disasters or de].

Balanced ] requires that different factors in the accumulation process expand in appropriate proportions. But markets themselves cannot spontaneously create that balance, in fact what drives business activity is precisely the imbalances between ]: inequality is the motor of growth. This partly explains why the worldwide pattern of economic growth is very uneven and unequal, even although markets have existed almost everywhere for a very long-time. Some people argue that it also explains government regulation of market trade and ].

=== Capital accumulation as social relation ===
"Accumulation of capital" sometimes also refers in Marxist writings to the reproduction of capitalist ] (institutions) on a larger scale over time, i.e., the expansion of the size of the ] and of the wealth owned by the ].

This interpretation emphasises that capital ownership, predicated on command over labor, is a social relation: the growth of capital implies the growth of the ] (a "]"). In the first volume of ''Das Kapital'' Marx had illustrated this idea with reference to ]'s theory of colonisation: {{Quotation|Wakefield discovered that in the Colonies, property in money, means of subsistence, machines, and other means of production, does not as yet stamp a man as a capitalist if there be wanting the correlative – the wage-worker, the other man who is compelled to sell himself of his own free-will. He discovered that capital is not a thing, but a social relation between persons, established by the instrumentality of things. Mr. Peel, he moans, took with him from England to Swan River, West Australia, means of subsistence and of production to the amount of £50,000. Mr. Peel had the foresight to bring with him, besides, 3,000 persons of the working-class, men, women, and children. Once arrived at his destination, 'Mr. Peel was left without a servant to make his bed or fetch him water from the river.' Unhappy Mr. Peel, who provided for everything except the export of English modes of production to Swan River!|}}

In ] of ''Das Kapital'', Marx refers to the "fetishism of capital" reaching its highest point with ''interest-bearing capital'', because now capital seems to grow of its own accord without anybody doing anything.

{{Quotation|The relations of capital assume their most externalised and most fetish-like form in interest-bearing capital. We have here <math>M - M'</math>, money creating more money, self-expanding value, without the process that effectuates these two extremes. In merchant's capital, <math>M - C - M'</math>, there is at least the general form of the capitalistic movement, although it confines itself solely to the sphere of circulation, so that profit appears merely as profit derived from alienation; but it is at least seen to be the product of a social relation, not the product of a mere thing. (...) This is obliterated in <math>M - M'</math>, the form of interest-bearing capital. (...) The thing (money, commodity, value) is now capital even as a mere thing, and capital appears as a mere thing. The result of the entire process of reproduction appears as a property inherent in the thing itself. It depends on the owner of the money, i.e., of the commodity in its continually exchangeable form, whether he wants to spend it as money or loan it out as capital. In interest-bearing capital, therefore, this automatic fetish, self-expanding value, money generating money, are brought out in their pure state and in this form it no longer bears the birth-marks of its origin. The ] is consummated in the relation of a thing, of money, to itself. Instead of the actual transformation of money into capital, we see here only form without content.|}}


== Supply and demand == == Supply and demand ==
{{Main|Supply and demand}}
] at each price (demand D): the diagram shows a positive shift in demand from D<sub>1</sub> to D<sub>2</sub>, resulting in an increase in price (P) and quantity sold (Q) of the product]]
] at each price (demand D): the diagram shows a positive shift in demand from D<sub>1</sub> to D<sub>2</sub>, resulting in an increase in price (P) and quantity sold (Q) of the product.]]
In capitalist economic structures, supply and demand is an ] of ] in a ]. It concludes that in a ], the ] for a particular ] will vary until it settles at a point where the quantity demanded by consumers (at current price) will equal the quantity supplied by producers (at current price), resulting in an ] for price and ].
In capitalist economic structures, supply and demand is an ] of ] in a ]. It postulates that in a ], the ] for a particular ] will vary until it settles at a point where the quantity demanded by consumers (at the current price) will equal the quantity supplied by producers (at the current price), resulting in an ] for price and ].


The four basic laws of ] and ] are:<ref name="besanko-and-braeutigam-2010">{{Cite book | last = Besanko | first = David | last2 = Braeutigam | first2 = Ronald | year = 2010 | title = Microeconomics | publisher = Wiley | edition = 4th }}</ref>{{rp|37}} The "basic laws" of ] and ], as described by David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam, are the following four:<ref name="besanko-and-braeutigam-2010">{{cite book |last1=Besanko |first1=David |last2=Braeutigam |first2=Ronald |year=2010 |title=Microeconomics |publisher=] |edition=4th}}</ref>{{rp|37}}
# If demand increases (demand curve shifts to the right) and supply remains unchanged, then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price. # If demand increases (demand curve shifts to the right) and supply remains unchanged, then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price.
# If demand decreases (demand curve shifts to the left) and supply remains unchanged, then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price. # If demand decreases (demand curve shifts to the left) and supply remains unchanged, then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price.
Line 299: Line 220:
# If demand remains unchanged and supply decreases (supply curve shifts to the left), then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price. # If demand remains unchanged and supply decreases (supply curve shifts to the left), then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price.


=== Supply schedule ===
=== Graphical representation of supply and demand ===
A supply schedule is a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied.<ref name="Boundless Economics 2017">{{cite web |title=Supply |website=Boundless Economics |date=13 June 2017 |url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/boundless-economics/chapter/supply/ |access-date=27 October 2021}}</ref>
Although it is normal to regard the quantity demanded and the quantity supplied as ] of the price of the goods, the standard graphical representation, usually attributed to ], has price on the vertical axis and quantity on the horizontal axis, the opposite of the standard convention for the representation of a mathematical function.

Since determinants of supply and demand other than the price of the goods in question are not explicitly represented in the supply-demand diagram, changes in the values of these variables are represented by moving the supply and demand curves (often described as "shifts" in the curves). By contrast, responses to changes in the price of the good are represented as movements along unchanged supply and demand curves.

==== Supply schedule ====
A supply schedule is a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied. Under the assumption of ], supply is determined by ]. That is: firms will produce additional output while the cost of producing an extra unit of output is less than the price they would receive.

A hike in the cost of raw goods would decrease supply, shifting costs up, while a discount would increase supply, shifting costs down and hurting producers as producer surplus decreases.

By its very nature, conceptualising a supply curve requires the firm to be a perfect competitor (i.e. to have no influence over the market price). This is true because each point on the supply curve is the answer to the question "If this firm is ''faced with'' this potential price, how much output will it be able to and willing to sell?" If a firm has market power, its decision of how much output to provide to the market influences the market price, therefore the firm is not "faced with" any price, and the question becomes less relevant.

Economists distinguish between the supply curve of an individual firm and between the market supply curve. The market supply curve is obtained by summing the quantities supplied by all suppliers at each potential price. Thus, in the graph of the supply curve, individual firms' supply curves are added horizontally to obtain the market supply curve.

Economists also distinguish the short-run market supply curve from the long-run market supply curve. In this context, two things are assumed constant by definition of the short run: the availability of one or more fixed inputs (typically ]), and the number of firms in the industry. In the long-run, firms can adjust their holdings of physical capital, enabling them to better adjust their quantity supplied at any given price. Furthermore, in the long-run potential competitors can ] or exit the industry in response to market conditions. For both of these reasons, long-run market supply curves are generally flatter than their short-run counterparts.

The determinants of supply are:
# Production costs: how much a goods costs to be produced. Production costs are the cost of the inputs; primarily labor, capital, energy and materials. They depend on the technology used in production, and/or technological advances. See: ].
# Firms' expectations about future prices.
# Number of suppliers.

==== Demand schedule ====
A demand schedule, depicted graphically as the ], represents the amount of some ] that buyers are willing and able to purchase at various prices, assuming all determinants of demand other than the price of the good in question, such as income, tastes and preferences, the price of ]s, and the price of ]s, remain the same. Following the ], the demand curve is almost always represented as downward-sloping, meaning that as price decreases, consumers will buy more of the good.<ref name="axes">Note that unlike most ], supply & demand curves are plotted with the independent variable (price) on the vertical axis and the dependent variable (quantity supplied or demanded) on the horizontal axis.</ref>

Just like the supply curves reflect ] curves, demand curves are determined by ] curves.<ref>{{cite web|title=Marginal Utility and Demand|url=http://www.amosweb.com/cgi-bin/awb_nav.pl?s=wpd&c=dsp&k=marginal+utility+and+demand|accessdate=9 February 2007}}</ref> Consumers will be willing to buy a given quantity of a good, at a given price, if the marginal utility of additional consumption is equal to the ] determined by the price, that is the marginal utility of alternative consumption choices. The demand schedule is defined as the ''willingness'' and ''ability'' of a consumer to purchase a given product in a given frame of time.

While the aforementioned demand curve is generally downward-sloping, there may be rare examples of goods that have upward-sloping demand curves. Two different hypothetical types of goods with upward-sloping demand curves are ]s (an inferior but ] good) and ]s (goods made more fashionable by a higher price).

By its very nature, conceptualising a demand curve requires that the purchaser be a perfect competitor – that is, that the purchaser has no influence over the market price. This is true because each point on the demand curve is the answer to the question "If this buyer is ''faced with'' this potential price, how much of the product will it purchase?" If a buyer has market power, so its decision of how much to buy influences the market price, then the buyer is not "faced with" any price, and the question is meaningless.


=== Demand schedule ===
Like with supply curves, economists distinguish between the demand curve of an individual and the market demand curve. The market demand curve is obtained by summing the quantities demanded by all consumers at each potential price. Thus, in the graph of the demand curve, individuals' demand curves are added horizontally to obtain the market demand curve.
A demand schedule, depicted graphically as the ], represents the amount of some ] that buyers are willing and able to purchase at various prices, assuming all determinants of demand other than the price of the good in question, such as income, tastes and preferences, the price of ]s and the price of ]s, remain the same. According to the ], the demand curve is almost always represented as downward sloping, meaning that as price decreases, consumers will buy more of the good.<ref name="axes">Unlike most ], supply & demand curves are plotted with the independent variable (price) on the vertical axis and the dependent variable (quantity supplied or demanded) on the horizontal axis.</ref>


Just like the supply curves reflect ] curves, demand curves are determined by ] curves.<ref>{{cite web|title=Marginal Utility and Demand |url=http://www.amosweb.com/cgi-bin/awb_nav.pl?s=wpd&c=dsp&k=marginal+utility+and+demand |access-date=9 February 2007 |archive-date=6 November 2006 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20061106121422/http://www.amosweb.com/cgi-bin/awb_nav.pl?s=wpd&c=dsp&k=marginal+utility+and+demand |url-status=live}}</ref>
The determinants of demand are:
# Income.
# Tastes and preferences.
# Prices of related goods and services.
# Consumers' expectations about future prices and incomes that can be checked.
# Number of potential consumers.


=== Equilibrium === === Equilibrium ===
{{Further information|Economic equilibrium}} {{further|Economic equilibrium}}
In the context of supply and demand, economic equilibrium refers to a state where economic forces such as ] are balanced and in the absence of external influences the (]) values of economic variables will not change. For example, in the standard text-book model of ], equilibrium occurs at the point at which quantity demanded and quantity supplied are equal.<ref>{{cite book |authorlink=Hal Varian |first=Hal R. |last=Varian |title=Microeconomic Analysis |edition=Third |publisher=Norton |location=New York |year=1992 |isbn=0-393-95735-7 }}</ref> Market equilibrium in this case refers to a condition where a market price is established through competition such that the amount of goods or services sought by ] is equal to the amount of goods or services produced by ]. This price is often called the competitive price or ] price and will tend not to change unless demand or supply changes and the quantity is called "competitive quantity" or market clearing quantity. In the context of supply and demand, economic equilibrium refers to a state where economic forces such as ] are balanced and in the absence of external influences the (]) values of economic variables will not change. For example, in the standard text-book model of ] equilibrium occurs at the point at which quantity demanded and quantity supplied are equal.<ref>{{cite book |author-link=Hal Varian |first=Hal R. |last=Varian |title=Microeconomic Analysis |edition=Third |publisher=Norton |location=New York |year=1992 |isbn=978-0-393-95735-8 |url=https://archive.org/details/microeconomicana00vari_0}}</ref> Market equilibrium, in this case, refers to a condition where a market price is established through competition such that the amount of goods or services sought by ] is equal to the amount of goods or services produced by ]. This price is often called the competitive price or ] price and will tend not to change unless demand or supply changes.


=== Partial equilibrium === === Partial equilibrium ===
{{Main article|Partial equilibrium}} {{Main|Partial equilibrium}}
Partial equilibrium, as the name suggests, takes into consideration only a part of the market to attain equilibrium. Jain proposes (attributed to ]): "A partial equilibrium is one which is based on only a restricted range of data, a standard example is price of a single product, the prices of all other products being held fixed during the analysis".<ref>{{cite book |last=Jain |first=T.R. |title=Microeconomics and Basic Mathematics |year=2006 |publisher=VK Publications |location=New Delhi |isbn=978-81-87140-89-4 |page=28 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=fUUoFwco2Z8C }}{{Dead link|date=January 2023 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}</ref>
Partial equilibrium, as the name suggests, takes into consideration only a part of the market to attain equilibrium.

Jain proposes (attributed to ]): "A partial equilibrium is one which is based on only a restricted range of data, a standard example is price of a single product, the prices of all other products being held fixed during the analysis."<ref>{{cite book|last=Jain|first=T.R.|title=Microeconomics and Basic Mathematics|year=2006|publisher=VK Publications|location=New Delhi|isbn=81-87140-89-5|page=28|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=fUUoFwco2Z8C&printsec=frontcover#v=onepage&q&f=false}}</ref>

The supply-and-demand model is a partial equilibrium model of ], where the clearance on the ] of some specific ] is obtained independently from prices and quantities in other markets. In other words, the prices of all ] and ], as well as ] levels of ]s are constant. This makes analysis much simpler than in a ] model which includes an entire economy.

Here the dynamic process is that prices adjust until supply equals demand. It is a powerfully simple technique that allows one to study ], ] and ]. The stringency of the simplifying assumptions inherent in this approach make the model considerably more tractable, but may produce results which while seemingly precise do not effectively model real world economic phenomena.

Partial equilibrium analysis examines the effects of policy action in creating equilibrium only in that particular sector or market which is directly affected, ignoring its effect in any other market or industry assuming that they being small will have little impact if any.

Hence this analysis is considered to be useful in constricted markets.

] first formalised the idea of a one-period economic equilibrium of the general economic system, but it was French economist ] and English political economist ] who developed tractable models to analyse an economic system.

=== Empirical estimation ===
Demand and supply relations in a market can be statistically estimated from price, quantity, and other ] with sufficient information in the model. This can be done with ''] methods of estimation'' in ]. Such methods allow solving for the model-relevant "structural coefficients", the estimated algebraic counterparts of the theory. The '']'' is a common issue in "structural estimation". Typically, data on ] variables (that is: variables other than price and quantity, both of which are ] variables) are needed to perform such an estimation. An alternative to "structural estimation" is ] estimation, which regresses each of the endogenous variables on the respective exogenous variables.

=== Macroeconomic uses of demand and supply ===
Demand and supply have also been generalised to explain ] variables in a ], including the ] and the general ]. The ] may be the most direct application of supply and demand to macroeconomics, but other macroeconomic models also use supply and demand. Compared to ] uses of demand and supply, different (and more controversial) theoretical considerations apply to such ] counterparts as ] and ]. Demand and supply are also used in macroeconomic theory to relate ] and money demand to ]s, and to relate labor supply and labor demand to wage rates.


=== History === === History ===
According to Hamid S. Hosseini, the power of supply and demand was understood to some extent by several early Muslim scholars, such as fourteenth-century ] scholar ], who wrote: "If desire for goods increases while its availability decreases, its price rises. On the other hand, if availability of the good increases and the desire for it decreases, the price comes down."<ref name=Hosseini>{{cite book |title=A Companion to the History of Economic Thought |chapter=Contributions of Medieval Muslim Scholars to the History of Economics and their Impact: A Refutation of the Schumpeterian Great Gap |last=Hosseini |first=Hamid S. |editor=Biddle, Jeff E. |editor2=Davis, Jon B. |editor3=Samuels, Warren J. |year=2003 |publisher=Blackwell |location=Malden, Massachusetts |isbn=0-631-22573-0 |doi=10.1002/9780470999059.ch3 |pages=28–45 }} (citing Hamid S. Hosseini, 1995. "Understanding the Market Mechanism Before Adam Smith: Economic Thought in Medieval Islam," ''History of Political Economy'', Vol. 27, No. 3, 539–61).</ref> According to Hamid S. Hosseini, the "power of supply and demand" was discussed to some extent by several early Muslim scholars, such as fourteenth century ] scholar ], who wrote: "If desire for goods increases while its availability decreases, its price rises. On the other hand, if availability of the good increases and the desire for it decreases, the price comes down".<ref name=Hosseini>{{cite book |title=A Companion to the History of Economic Thought |chapter=Contributions of Medieval Muslim Scholars to the History of Economics and their Impact: A Refutation of the Schumpeterian Great Gap |last=Hosseini |first=Hamid S. |editor1-last=Biddle |editor1-first=Jeff E. |editor2-last=Davis |editor2-first=Jon B. |editor3-last=Samuels |editor3-first=Warren J. |year=2003 |publisher=Blackwell |location=Malden, Massachusetts |isbn=978-0-631-22573-7 |doi=10.1002/9780470999059.ch3 |pages=28–45 }} (citing Hamid S. Hosseini, 1995. "Understanding the Market Mechanism Before Adam Smith: Economic Thought in Medieval Islam," ''History of Political Economy'', Vol. 27, No. 3, 539–561).</ref>


]]] ]]]
]'s 1691 work ''Some Considerations on the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money''.<ref>John Locke (1691) </ref> includes an early and clear description of supply and demand and their relationship. In this description demand is ]: "The price of any commodity rises or falls by the proportion of the number of buyer and sellers” and “that which regulates the price... is nothing else but their quantity in proportion to their rent". ]'s 1691 work ''Some Considerations on the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money''<ref>John Locke (1691) {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150324135856/https://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/locke/contents.htm |date=24 March 2015 }}</ref> includes an early and clear description{{primary source inline|date=February 2022}} of supply and demand and their relationship. In this description, demand is ]: "The price of any commodity rises or falls by the proportion of the number of buyer and sellers" and "that which regulates the price... is nothing else but their quantity in proportion to their rent".


The phrase "supply and demand" was first used by ] in his ''Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy'', published in 1767. ] used the phrase in his 1776 book '']'', and ] titled one chapter of his 1817 work '']'' "On the Influence of Demand and Supply on Price".<ref name=Humphrey>Thomas M. Humphrey, 1992. "Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall", ''Economic Review'', Mar/Apr, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, pp. .</ref> ] titled one chapter of his 1817 work '']'' "On the Influence of Demand and Supply on Price".<ref name=Humphrey>Thomas M. Humphrey, 1992. "Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall", ''Economic Review'', Mar/Apr, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, pp. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121019100824/http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/economic_review/1992/pdf/er780201.pdf |date=19 October 2012 }}.</ref>
In ''Principles of Political Economy and Taxation'', Ricardo more rigorously laid down the idea of the assumptions that were used to build his ideas of supply and demand.


In his 1870 essay "On the Graphical Representation of Supply and Demand", ] in the course of "introduc the diagrammatic method into the English economic literature" published the first drawing of supply and demand curves therein,<ref>A.D. Brownlie and M.F. Lloyd Prichard, 1963. "Professor Fleeming Jenkin, 1833–1885 Pioneer in Engineering and Political Economy", ''Oxford Economic Papers'', 15(3), p. 211.</ref> including ] from a shift of supply or demand and application to the labor market.<ref>Fleeming Jenkin, 1870. "The Graphical Representation of the Laws of Supply and Demand, and their Application to Labour", in Alexander Grant, ed., ''Recess Studies'', Edinburgh. Ch. VI, pp. 151–185. Edinburgh. Scroll to chapter {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200716052536/https://books.google.com/books?id=NC5BAAAAIAAJ |date=16 July 2020 }}.</ref> The model was further developed and popularized by ] in the 1890 textbook '']''.<ref name="Humphrey" />
In ''The Wealth of Nations'', Smith generally assumed that the supply price was fixed but that its "merit" (value) would decrease as its "scarcity" increased, in effect what was later called the law of demand also. Ricardo, in ''Principles of Political Economy and Taxation'', more rigorously laid down the idea of the assumptions that were used to build his ideas of supply and demand. ] first developed a mathematical model of supply and demand in his 1838 ''Researches into the Mathematical Principles of Wealth'', including diagrams.


== Types ==
During the late 19th century the marginalist school of thought emerged. This field mainly was started by ], ], and ]. The key idea was that the price was set by the most expensive price, that is, the price at the margin. This was a substantial change from Adam Smith's thoughts on determining the supply price.
There are many variants of capitalism in existence that differ according to country and region.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Hall |first1=Peter A. |last2=Soskice |first2=David |title=Varieties Of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage |date=20 September 2001 |publisher=Oxford University Press, U.S.A. |isbn=0-19-924775-7}}</ref> They vary in their institutional makeup and by their economic policies. The common features among all the different forms of capitalism are that they are predominantly based on the private ownership of the means of production and the production of goods and services for profit; the market-based allocation of resources; and the accumulation of capital.


They include advanced capitalism, corporate capitalism, finance capitalism, free-market capitalism, mercantilism, state capitalism and welfare capitalism. Other theoretical variants of capitalism include ], ], ], ], ], and ].
In his 1870 essay "On the Graphical Representation of Supply and Demand", ] in the course of "introduc the diagrammatic method into the English economic literature" published the first drawing of supply and demand curves therein,<ref>A. D. Brownlie and M. F. Lloyd Prichard, 1963. "Professor Fleeming Jenkin, 1833–1885 Pioneer in Engineering and Political Economy", ''Oxford Economic Papers'', 15(3), p. 211.</ref> including ] from a shift of supply or demand and application to the labor market.<ref>Fleeming Jenkin, 1870. "The Graphical Representation of the Laws of Supply and Demand, and their Application to Labour", in Alexander Grant, ed., ''Recess Studies'', Edinburgh. Ch. VI, pp. 151–85. Edinburgh. Scroll to chapter .</ref> The model was further developed and popularized by ] in the 1890 textbook '']''.<ref name="Humphrey" />


== Capitalism and war == === Advanced ===
{{Main|Advanced capitalism}}
War typically causes the diversion, destruction and creation of capital assets as capital assets are both destroyed or consumed and diverted to types of production needed to fight the war. Many assets are wasted and in some few cases created specifically to fight a war. War driven demands may be a powerful stimulus for the accumulation of capital and production capability in limited areas and market expansion outside the immediate theatre of war. Often this has induced laws against perceived and real ].
Advanced capitalism is the situation that pertains to a society in which the capitalist model has been integrated and developed deeply and extensively for a prolonged period. Various writers identify ] as an influential early theorist of advanced capitalism, even if he did not use the term himself. In his writings, Gramsci sought to explain how capitalism had adapted to avoid the revolutionary overthrow that had seemed inevitable in the 19th century. At the heart of his explanation was the decline of raw coercion as a tool of class power, replaced by use of ] institutions to manipulate public ideology in the capitalists' favour.<ref>Lears, T.J. Jackson (1985) "The Concept of Cultural Hegemony"</ref><ref>Holub, Renate (2005) ''Antonio Gramsci: Beyond Marxism and Postmodernism''</ref><ref>] (2012) ''Ecology and Revolution: Global Crisis and the Political Challenge''</ref>


] has been a major contributor to the analysis of advanced-capitalistic societies. Habermas observed four general features that characterise advanced capitalism:
The total hours worked in the United States rose by 34 percent during World War II, even though the military draft reduced the civilian labor force by 11 percent.<ref>{{cite journal |first=Ellen R. |last=Grattan |first2=Lee E. |last2=Ohanian |title=The macroeconomic effects of big fiscal shocks: the case of world war II |work=Minneapolis Federal Reserve, Working Paper 599 |date=December 1999 |url=https://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/wp/wp599.pdf }}</ref>
# Concentration of industrial activity in a few large firms.
# Constant reliance on the state to stabilise the economic system.
# A formally democratic government that legitimises the activities of the state and dissipates opposition to the system.
# The use of nominal wage increases to pacify the most restless segments of the work force.<ref>Habermas, 1988: 37, 75.</ref>


=== Corporate ===
] at ], 1942: the common view among economic historians is that the ] ended with the advent of World War II]]
{{Main|Corporate capitalism}}
War destruction can be illustrated by looking at ]. Industrial war damage was heaviest in Japan, where 1/4 of factory buildings and 1/3 of plant & equipment were destroyed; 1/7 of electric power-generating capacity was destroyed and 6/7 of oil refining capacity. The Japanese merchant fleet lost 80% of their ships. In Germany in 1944, when air attacks were heaviest, 6.5% of machine tools were damaged or destroyed, but around 90% were later repaired. About 10% of steel production capacity was lost. In Europe, the United States and the Soviet Union enormous resources were accumulated and ultimately dissipated as planes, ships, tanks, etc. were built and then lost or destroyed.
{{See also|Crony capitalism|State monopoly capitalism}}
Corporate capitalism is a free or mixed-market capitalist economy characterized by the dominance of hierarchical and bureaucratic corporations.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Barnett |first=H C |date=January 1981 |title=Crime and Delinquency |url=https://www.ojp.gov/ncjrs/virtual-library/abstracts/corporate-capitalism-corporate-crime |journal=]}}</ref>


=== Finance ===
Germany's total war damage was estimated at about 17.5% of the pre-war total capital stock by value, i.e. about 1/6. In the ] area alone, there were 8 million refugees lacking basic necessities. In 1945, less than 10% of the railways were still operating. 2395 rail bridges were destroyed and a total of 7500 bridges, 10,000 locomotives and more than 100,000 goods wagons were destroyed. Less than 40% of the remaining locomotives were operational.
{{Main|Finance capitalism}}
{{See also|Capitalist mode of production (Marxist theory)}}
Finance capitalism is the subordination of processes of ] to the accumulation of ] profits in a ]. In their critique of capitalism, ] and ] both emphasise the role of ] as the determining and ] interest in capitalist society, particularly in the ].<ref>] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150402214909/https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1916/imp-hsc/ch03.htm |date=2 April 2015 }}</ref><ref>{{cite magazine|url=http://monthlyreview.org/2009/10/01/monopoly-finance-capital-and-the-paradox-of-accumulation/|title= Monopoly-Finance Capital and the Paradox of Accumulation |first1=John Bellamy |last1=Foster |author1-link=John Bellamy Foster |first2=Robert W. |last2=McChesney |author2-link=Robert W. McChesney |date=1 October 2009 |magazine=] |access-date=27 August 2016 |archive-date=28 August 2016 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160828081218/http://monthlyreview.org/2009/10/01/monopoly-finance-capital-and-the-paradox-of-accumulation/ |url-status=live}}</ref>


] is credited with first bringing the term finance capitalism into prominence through ''Finance Capital'', his 1910 study of the links between German trusts, banks and monopolies—a study subsumed by ] into '']'' (1917), his analysis of the imperialist relations of the great world powers.<ref>Frederic Jameson, 'Culture and Finance Capital', in ''The Jameson Reader'' (2005) p. 257</ref> Lenin concluded that the banks at that time operated as "the chief nerve centres of the whole capitalist system of national economy".<ref>Quoted in E.H. Carr, ''The Bolshevik Revolution 2'' (1971) p. 137</ref> For the ] (founded in 1919), the phrase "dictatorship of finance capitalism"<ref>Quoted in F.A Voight, ''Unto Caesar'' (1938) p. 22</ref> became a regular one.
However, by the first quarter of 1946 European rail traffic, which was given assistance and preferences (by western appointed military governors) for resources and material as an essential asset, regained its prewar operational level. At the end of the year, 90% of Germany's railway lines were operating again. In retrospect, the rapidity of infrastructure reconstruction appears astonishing.


] would later point to two earlier periods when finance capitalism had emerged in human history—with the Genoese in the 16th century and with the Dutch in the 17th and 18th centuries—although at those points it developed from commercial capitalism.<ref>C. J.Calhoun/G. Derluguian, ''Business as Usual'' (2011) p. 57</ref>{{request quotation|date=December 2016}} ] extended Braudel's analysis to suggest that a predominance of finance capitalism is a recurring, long-term phenomenon, whenever a previous phase of commercial/industrial capitalist expansion reaches a plateau.<ref>Jameson, pp. 259–260</ref>
Initially, in May 1945 newly installed United States president ]'s directive had been that no steps would be taken towards economic rehabilitation of Germany. In fact, the initial industry plan of 1946 prohibited production in excess of half of the 1938 level; the iron and steel industry was allowed to produce only less than a third of pre-war output. These plans were rapidly revised and better plans were instituted. In 1946, over 10% of Germany's physical capital stock (plant & equipment) was also dismantled and confiscated, most of it going to the USSR. By 1947, industrial production in Germany was at 1/3 of the 1938 level, and industrial investment at about 1/2 the 1938 level.


=== Free market ===
The first big strike-wave in the Ruhr occurred in early 1947{{snd}}it was about food rations and housing, but soon there were demands for nationalisation. The United States appointed military governor (Newman) however stated at the time that he had the power to break strikes by withholding food rations. The clear message was: "no work, no eat". As the military controls in Western Germany were nearly all relinquished and the Germans were allowed to rebuild their own economy with Marshal Plan aid things rapidly improved. By 1951, German industrial production had overtaken the prewar level. The ] funds were important, but, after the currency reform (which permitted German capitalists to revalue their assets) and the establishment of a new political system, much more important was the commitment of the United States to ''rebuilding'' German capitalism and establishing a free market economy and government, rather than keeping Germany in a weak position. Initially, average real wages remained low, lower even than in 1938, until the early 1950s, while profitability was unusually high. So the total investment fund, aided by credits, was also high, resulting in a high rate of capital accumulation which was nearly all reinvested in new construction or new tools. This was called the ] or ''"Wirtschaftswunder"''.<ref>Armstrong, Glyn & Harrison, ''Capitalism since world war 2''. Fontana, 1984. See also Karl Hardach, "Germany 1914–1917", in: Carlo M. Cipolla, ''The Fontana History of Europe'', Part One. Fontana, 1976, p. 224.</ref>
{{Main|Free-market capitalism}}
{{See also|Laissez-faire}}
A capitalist free-market economy is an economic system where prices for goods and services are set entirely by the forces of ] and are expected, by its adherents, to reach their point of ] without intervention by government policy. It typically entails support for highly ] and ] of the ].<ref>{{Cite web |last=Jahan |first=Sarwat |last2=Saber Mahmud |first2=Ahmed |title=What Is Capitalism? |url=https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/fandd/issues/Series/Back-to-Basics/Capitalism |website=]}}</ref> ''Laissez-faire'' capitalism is a more extensive form of this free-market economy, but one in which the role of the state is limited to protecting ].<ref>{{Cite web |title=Laissez-faire |url=https://www.britannica.com/money/laissez-faire |website=]}}</ref> In ] theory, property rights are protected by private firms and market-generated law. According to anarcho-capitalists, this entails property rights without statutory law through market-generated tort, contract and property law, and self-sustaining private industry.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Anarcho-capitalism |url=https://www.britannica.com/money/anarcho-capitalism |website=]}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |last=Perumal J. |first=Prashanth |date=13 December 2023 |title=Understanding the debates around anarcho-capitalism |url=https://www.thehindu.com/specials/text-and-context/understanding-the-debates-around-anarcho-capitalism/article67631934.ece |url-status=unfit |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20231213083528/https://www.thehindu.com/specials/text-and-context/understanding-the-debates-around-anarcho-capitalism/article67631934.ece |archive-date=13 December 2023 |website=]}}</ref>


] argued that free market exchange and capitalism are to some degree opposed; free market exchange involves ] public transactions and a large number of ], while capitalism involves a small number of participants using their capital to control the market via private transactions, control of information, and limitation of competition.<ref name="Braudel Ranum Ranum Johns Hopkins University 1977 p. 47-63">{{cite book |last1=Braudel |first1=F. |author-link=Fernand Braudel |last2=Ranum |first2=P.M. |last3=Ranum |first3=P.P. |title=Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism |publisher=] |series=Johns Hopkins symposia in comparative history |year=1977 |isbn=978-0-8018-1901-8 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=1eVdAAAAIAAJ |access-date=6 April 2022 |pages=47–63}}</ref>
In Italy, the victorious Allies did three things in 1945: they imposed their absolute military authority; they quickly disarmed the Italian partisans from a very large stock of weapons; and they agreed to a state guarantee of wage payments, as well as a veto on all sackings of workers from their jobs.<ref>{{cite book |first=Paul |last=Ginsborg |title=A History of Contemporary Italy – Society and Politics 1943–1988 |location=London |publisher=Penguin Books |year=1990 |page=70 |isbn=0-14-012496-9 }}</ref> Although the Italian Communist Party grew very large immediately after the war ended{{snd}}it achieved a membership of 1.7 million people in a population of 45 million{{snd}}it was outmaneouvred<!-- spelling? this seems incorrect --> through a complicated political battle by the Christian Democrats, after three years.<ref>Ginsborg (1990), chapter 3.</ref> In the 1950s, an economic boom began in Italy, at first fuelled by internal demand, and then also by exports.<ref>Ginsborg (1990), p. 214.</ref>


=== Mercantile ===
In modern times, it has often been possible to rebuild physical capital assets destroyed in wars completely within the space of about 10 years, except in cases of severe pollution by ] or other kinds of irreparable devastation. However, damage to ] has been much more devastating, in terms of fatalities (in the case of World War II, about 55 million deaths), permanent physical disability, enduring ethnic hostility and psychological injuries which have effects for at least several generations.
{{Main|Mercantilism}}
{{See also|Protectionism}}
] in the early 19th century]]
Mercantilism is a nationalist form of early capitalism that came into existence approximately in the late 16th century. It is characterized by the intertwining of national business interests with state-interest and imperialism. Consequently, the state apparatus is used to advance national business interests abroad. An example of this is ] who were only allowed to trade with and purchase goods from their respective mother countries (e.g., United Kingdom, France and Portugal). Mercantilism was driven by the belief that the wealth of a nation is increased through a positive balance of trade with other nations—it corresponds to the phase of capitalist development sometimes called the ].<ref>{{Cite web |title=Mercantilism |url=https://www.britannica.com/money/mercantilism |website=]}}</ref>


== Types of capitalism == === Social ===
{{Main|Social market economy}}
There are many variants of capitalism in existence that differ according to country and region. They vary in their institutional makeup and by their economic policies. The common features among all the different forms of capitalism is that they are based on the production of goods and services for profit, predominantly market-based allocation of resources, and they are structured upon the accumulation of capital. The major forms of capitalism are listed hereafter:
{{See also|Nordic model}}
A social market economy is a free-market or mixed-market capitalist system, sometimes classified as a ], where government intervention in price formation is kept to a minimum, but the state provides significant services in areas such as social security, health care, unemployment benefits and the recognition of ] through national ] arrangements.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Müller-Armack |first=Alfred |date=28 July 2006 |title=The Social Market Economy as an Economic and Social order |url=https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/00346767800000020 |journal=]}}</ref>


This model is prominent in Western and Northern European countries as well as Japan, albeit in slightly different configurations. The vast majority of enterprises are privately owned in this economic model. Rhine capitalism is the contemporary model of capitalism and adaptation of the social market model that exists in continental Western Europe today.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Rhenish Capitalism |url=https://www.oxfordreference.com/display/10.1093/oi/authority.20110803100418483 |website=]}}</ref>
=== Advanced capitalism ===
{{Main article|Advanced capitalism}}
Advanced capitalism is the situation that pertains to a society in which the ] has been integrated and developed deeply and extensively for a prolonged period. Various writers identify ] as an influential early theorist of advanced capitalism, even if he did not use the term himself. In his writings Gramsci sought to explain how capitalism had adapted to avoid the revolutionary overthrow that had seemed inevitable in the 19th century. At the heart of his explanation was the decline of raw coercion as a tool of class power, replaced by use of ] institutions to manipulate public ideology in the capitalists' favour.<ref>Lears, T. J. Jackson (1985) "The Concept of Cultural Hegemony"</ref><ref>Holub, Renate (2005) ''Antonio Gramsci: Beyond Marxism and Postmodernism''</ref><ref>Boggs, Carl (2012) ''Ecology and Revolution: Global Crisis and the Political Challenge''</ref>


=== State ===
] has been a major contributor to the analysis of advanced-capitalistic societies. Habermas observed four general features that characterise advanced capitalism:
{{Main|State capitalism}}
* Concentration of industrial activity in a few large firms
State capitalism is a capitalist market economy dominated by state-owned enterprises, where the state enterprises are organized as commercial, profit-seeking businesses. The designation has been used broadly throughout the 20th century to designate a number of different economic forms, ranging from state-ownership in market economies to the command economies of the former ]. According to Aldo Musacchio, a professor at Harvard Business School, state capitalism is a system in which governments, whether democratic or autocratic, exercise a widespread influence on the economy either through direct ownership or various subsidies. Musacchio notes a number of differences between today's state capitalism and its predecessors. In his opinion, gone are the days when governments appointed bureaucrats to run companies: the world's largest state-owned enterprises are now traded on the public markets and kept in good health by large institutional investors. Contemporary state capitalism is associated with the ], ] and the economy of Norway.<ref>{{cite news |last=Musacchio |first=Aldo |url=http://www.economist.com/debate/days/view/802 |title=Economist Debates: State capitalism: Statements |newspaper=The Economist |access-date=20 June 2012 |archive-date=16 July 2012 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120716050641/http://economist.com/debate/days/view/802 |url-status=live }}</ref> Alternatively, ] defines state capitalism as "an economic system in which private capitalism is modified by a varying degree of government ownership and control".<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150703131303/http://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/state%20capitalism |date=3 July 2015 }}. ]. Retrieved 7 July 2015.</ref>
* Constant reliance on the state to stabilise the economic system
* A formally democratic government that legitimises the activities of the state and dissipates opposition to the system
* The use of nominal wage increases to pacify the most restless segments of the work force<ref>Habermas, 1988: 37, 75.</ref>


In ''Socialism: Utopian and Scientific'', ] argued that state-owned enterprises would characterize the final stage of capitalism, consisting of ownership and management of large-scale production and communication by the ].<ref>{{cite web |first=Frederick |last=Engels |author-link=Friedrich Engels |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/ch03.htm |title=Socialism: Utopian and Scientific (Chpt. 3) |publisher=] |access-date=8 January 2014 |archive-date=9 May 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200509191523/https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/ch03.htm |url-status=live}}</ref> In his writings, ] characterized the economy of Soviet Russia as state capitalist, believing state capitalism to be an early step toward the development of socialism.<ref>V.I. Lenin. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150907043921/https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1921/apr/21.htm |date=7 September 2015 }}. ''Lenin's Collected Works'', 1st English ed., Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1965, vol. 32, pp. 329–365.</ref><ref>V.I. Lenin. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150618071802/https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1922/nov/14b.htm |date=18 June 2015 }}. ''Lenin Collected Works'', Progress Publishers, 1971, Moscow, vol. 42, pp. 425c–427a.</ref>
=== Finance capitalism ===
{{See also|Capitalist mode of production (Marxist theory)}}
In their critique of capitalism, ] and ] both emphasise the role of "]" as the determining and ] interest in capitalist society, particularly in the ].<ref>] </ref><ref>{{cite web|url= http://monthlyreview.org/2009/10/01/monopoly-finance-capital-and-the-paradox-of-accumulation/|title= Monopoly-Finance Capital and the Paradox of Accumulation|first1= John Bellamy|last1= Foster|first2= Robert W. McChesney Topics:|last2= Financialization|first3= Global Economic|last3= Crisis|first4= Political|last4= Economy|date= 1 October 2009|publisher= ]}}</ref>


Some economists and left-wing academics including ] and ], as well as many Marxist philosophers and revolutionaries such as ] and ], argue that the economies of the former ] and Eastern Bloc represented a form of state capitalism because their internal organization within enterprises and the system of wage labor remained intact.<ref> {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190728140836/https://www.hetsa.org.au/pdf/34-A-08.pdf |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221009/https://www.hetsa.org.au/pdf/34-A-08.pdf |archive-date=9 October 2022 |url-status=live |date=28 July 2019 }}, M.C. Howard and J.E. King</ref><ref>] (1986). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150924051230/http://www.chomsky.info/articles/1986----.htm |date=24 September 2015 }}. ''Our Generation''. Retrieved 9 July 2015.</ref><ref>] (27 June 2015). {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180311070639/http://www.truth-out.org/news/item/31567-socialism-means-abolishing-the-distinction-between-bosses-and-employees |date=11 March 2018 }}. ''].'' Retrieved 9 July 2015.</ref><ref>{{cite web|first1=Raya |last1=Dunayevskaya |author-link1=Raya Dunayevskaya |date=1941 |url=https://www.marxists.org/archive/dunayevskaya/works/1941/ussr-capitalist.htm |title=The Union of Soviet Socialist Republics is a Capitalist Society |website=] |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191207212742/https://www.marxists.org/archive/dunayevskaya/works/1941/ussr-capitalist.htm |archive-date=7 December 2019}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|first1=C.L.R. |last1=James |author-link1=C.L.R. James |first2=Raya |last2=Dunayevskaya |author-link2=Raya Dunayevskaya |first3=Grace Lee |last3=Boggs |author-link3=Grace Lee Boggs |date=1950 |url=https://libcom.org/files/State%20capitalism%20and%20world%20revolution%20-%20CLR%20James.pdf |title=State Capitalism and World Revolution |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200619014753/https://libcom.org/files/State%20capitalism%20and%20world%20revolution%20-%20CLR%20James.pdf |archive-date=19 June 2020}}</ref>
] is credited{{by whom|date=December 2016}} with first bringing the term "finance capitalism" into prominence through ''Finance Capital'', his 1910 study of the links between German trusts, banks, and monopolies – a study subsumed by ] into '']'' (1917), his analysis of the imperialist relations of the great world powers.<ref>Frederic Jameson, 'Culture and Finance Capital', in ''The Jameson Reader'' (2005) p. 257</ref> Lenin concluded that the banks at that time operated as "the chief nerve centres of the whole capitalist system of national economy":<ref>Quoted in E. H. Carr, ''The Bolshevik Revolution 2'' (1971) p. 137</ref> for the ] (founded in 1919), the phrase "dictatorship of finance capitalism"<ref>Quoted in F. A Voight, ''Unto Caesar'' (1938) p. 22</ref> became a regular one.


The term is not used by ] economists to describe state ownership of the means of production. The economist ] argued that the designation of state capitalism was a new label for the old labels of state socialism and planned economy and differed only in non-essentials from these earlier designations.<ref>{{cite book|first=Ludwig |last=Von Mises |author-link=Ludwig Von Mises |title=Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis |publisher=LibertyClassics |place=Indianapolis |year=1979 |isbn=978-0-913966-63-1 |url=https://archive.org/details/socialismeconomi00vonm |access-date=31 May 2007 |quote=The socialist movement takes great pains to circulate frequently new labels for its ideally constructed state. Each worn-out label is replaced by another which raises hopes of an ultimate solution of the insoluble basic problem of Socialism—until it becomes obvious that nothing has been changed but the name. The most recent slogan is 'State Capitalism.' It is not commonly realized that this covers nothing more than what used to be called Planned Economy and State Socialism, and that State Capitalism, Planned Economy, and State Socialism diverge only in non-essentials from the "classic" ideal of egalitarian Socialism. |url-access=registration}}</ref>
] would later point to two earlier periods when finance capitalism had emerged in human history – with the Genoese in the 16th century and with the Dutch in the 17th and 18th centuries – although at those points it developed from commercial capitalism.<ref>C. J. Calhoun/G. Derluguian, ''Business as Usual'' (2011) p. 57</ref>{{qn|date=December 2016}} ] extended Braudel's analysis to suggest that a predominance of finance capitalism is a recurring, long-term phenomenon, whenever a previous phase of commercial/industrial capitalist expansion reaches a plateau.<ref>
Jameson, pp. 259–60
</ref>


=== Mercantilism === === Welfare ===
{{Main|Welfare capitalism}}
{{Main article|Mercantilism|Protectionism}}
{{See also|Economic interventionism|Mixed economy}}
] in the early 19th century]]
Welfare capitalism is capitalism that includes social welfare policies. Today, welfare capitalism is most often associated with the models of capitalism found in Central and Northern Europe such as the ], ] and Rhine capitalism. In some cases, welfare capitalism exists within a mixed economy, but welfare states can and do exist independently of policies common to mixed economies such as ] and extensive regulation.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Esping-Andersen |first=Gøsta |title=] |publisher=] |year=1990 |isbn=9780691028576}}</ref>
Mercantilism is a nationalist form of early capitalism that came into existence approximately in the late 16th century. It is characterized by the intertwining of national business interests to state-interest and imperialism, and consequently, the state apparatus is utilized to advance national business interests abroad. An example of this is colonists living in America who were only allowed to trade with and purchase goods from their respective mother countries (e.g. Britain, Portugal, France). Mercantilism was driven by the belief that the wealth of a nation is increased through a positive balance of trade with other nations; it corresponds to the phase of capitalist development sometimes called the ].


A mixed economy is a largely market-based capitalist economy consisting of both private and public ownership of the means of production and ] through macroeconomic policies intended to correct ]s, reduce unemployment and keep inflation low. The degree of intervention in markets varies among different countries. Some mixed economies such as France under ] also featured a degree of ] over a largely capitalist-based economy.
=== Free-market economy ===
{{See also|Free market|Laissez-faire}}
Free-market economy refers to a capitalist economic system where prices for goods and services are set freely by the forces of supply and demand and are allowed to reach their point of equilibrium without intervention by government policy. It typically entails support for highly competitive markets and private ownership of productive enterprises. ''Laissez-faire'' is a more extensive form of free-market economy where the role of the state is limited to protecting ].


Most modern capitalist economies are defined as mixed economies to some degree<ins>,</ins> however French economist ] state that capitalist economies might shift to a much more ''laissez-faire'' approach in the near future.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Piketty |first=Thomas |title=Le capital au XXIe siècle |year=2013 |isbn=978-2-02-108228-9 |pages=799, 800 |language=fr |chapter=Repenser l'impôt progressif sur le revenu |publisher=Éditions du Seuil |trans-chapter=To rethink income tax progressivity |quote=Si cette régressivité fiscale au sommet de la hiérarchie sociale devait se confirmer et s'amplifier à l'avenir, il est bien évident qu'une telle sécession fiscale des plus riches est potentiellement extrêmement dommageable pour le consentement fiscal dans son ensemble s'en trouve amoindri . Il est vital pour l'État social moderne que le système fiscal qui le sous-tend conserve un minimum de progressivité. |trans-quote=If tax regressivity on top of the social hierarchy may settle in and escalate in the future, it is obvious that such a tax secession between the richest and the other classes will be highly harmful towards the agreement over the taxation system which will weaken. It is essential for the modern social system that the taxation system preserve a sort of tax progressivity.}}</ref>
=== Social-market economy ===
{{Main article|Social market|Nordic model}}
A social-market economy is a nominally free-market system where government intervention in price formation is kept to a minimum but the state provides significant services in the area of social security, unemployment benefits and recognition of ] through national ] arrangements. This model is prominent in Western and Northern European countries, and Japan, albeit in slightly different configurations. The vast majority of enterprises are privately owned in this economic model.


=== Eco-capitalism ===
] refers to the contemporary model of capitalism and adaptation of the social market model that exists in continental Western Europe today.
], also known as "environmental capitalism" or (sometimes<ref>{{cite news|url=https://www.theguardian.com/world/2019/nov/24/b-corps-captalism-for-an-environmentally-endangered-age |title=Green capitalism sometimes also referring to sustainable businesses |first=Oliver |last=Balch |date=24 November 2019 |work=]}}</ref>) "green capitalism", is the view that ] exists in nature as "]" (]s that have ]) on which all ] depends. Therefore, governments should use ] ] (such as a ]) to resolve ]s.<ref>{{cite web|title=Definition of Eco-Capitalism |url=https://www.collinsdictionary.com/dictionary/english/eco-capitalism |website=collinsdictionary.com |access-date= 27 November 2015}}</ref>


The term "Blue Greens" is often applied to those who espouse eco-capitalism. Eco-capitalism can be thought of as the right-wing equivalent to ].<ref>{{cite web|title=The rise of green capitalism |url=http://roadtoparis.info/top-list/rise-green-capitalism/ |website=roadtoparis.info |access-date=27 November 2015}}</ref>{{request quotation|date=August 2019}}
=== State capitalism ===
{{Main article|State capitalism}}
State capitalism is a capitalist market economy dominated by state-owned enterprises, where the state enterprises are organized as commercial, profit-seeking businesses. The designation has been used broadly throughout the 20th century to designate a number of different economic forms, ranging from state-ownership in market economies to the command economies of the former ]. According to Aldo Musacchio, a professor at Harvard Business School, state capitalism is a system in which governments, whether democratic or autocratic, exercise a widespread influence on the economy either through direct ownership or various subsidies. Musacchio notes a number of differences between today's state capitalism and its predecessors. In his opinion, gone are the days when governments appointed bureaucrats to run companies: the world's largest state-owned enterprises are now traded on the public markets and kept in good health by large institutional investors. Contemporary state capitalism is associated with the ], ] and the economy of Norway.<ref>{{cite news |last=Musacchio |first=Aldo |url=http://www.economist.com/debate/days/view/802 |title=Economist Debates: State capitalism: Statements |work=The Economist}}</ref> Alternatively, ] defines state capitalism as "an economic system in which private capitalism is modified by a varying degree of government ownership and control".<ref>. ]. Retrieved 7 July 2015.</ref>


=== Sustainable capitalism ===
], in ''Socialism: Utopian and Scientific'', argued that state-owned enterprises would characterize the final stage of capitalism, consisting of ownership and management of large-scale production and communication by the ].<ref>{{cite web|author=Frederick Engels |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1880/soc-utop/ch03.htm |title=Socialism: Utopian and Scientific (Chpt. 3) |publisher=] |accessdate=8 January 2014}}</ref> In his writings, ] characterized the economy of Soviet Russia as state capitalist, believing state capitalism to be an early step toward the development of socialism.<ref>V. I. Lenin. . ''Lenin’s Collected Works'', 1st English Edition, Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1965, vol. 32, pp. 329–65.</ref><ref>V. I. Lenin. . ''Lenin Collected Works'', Progress Publishers, 1971, Moscow, vol. 42, pp. 425c–427a.</ref>
] is a conceptual form of capitalism based upon ] practices that seek to preserve humanity and the planet, while reducing ] and bearing a resemblance of capitalist ]. A capitalistic economy must expand to survive and find new markets to support this expansion.<ref>{{cite book |doi=10.1109/IPCC.2011.6087226 |chapter=The convergence of sustainable capitalism |title=2011 IEEE International Professional Communication Conference |pages=1–7 |year=2011 |last1=Mitra |first1=Basavadatta |last2=Gadhok |first2=Saagar |last3=Salhotra |first3=Shivam |last4=Agarwal |first4=Sakshi |isbn=978-1-61284-779-5 |s2cid=31292223 }}</ref> Capitalist systems are often destructive to the environment as well as certain individuals without access to proper representation. However, sustainability provides quite the opposite; it implies not only a continuation, but a ].<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Schweickart |first1=David |title=Is Sustainable Capitalism an Oxymoron? |journal=Perspectives on Global Development and Technology |date=1 January 2009 |volume=8 |issue=2–3 |pages=559–580 |doi=10.1163/156914909X424033 }}</ref> Sustainability is often thought of to be related to ], and sustainable capitalism applies sustainable principles to economic governance and social aspects of capitalism as well.


The importance of sustainable capitalism has been more recently recognized, but the concept is not new. Changes to the current economic model would have heavy social environmental and economic implications and require the efforts of individuals, as well as compliance of local, state and federal governments. Controversy surrounds the concept as it requires an increase in sustainable practices and a marked decrease in current consumptive behaviors.<ref name=":2">{{Cite book |title=Sustainable Capitalism and the Pursuit of Well-Being.|last=E.|first=Harrison, Neil|date=1 January 2013|publisher=Routledge|isbn=978-1-306-21804-7|oclc=866837827}}{{page needed|date=March 2019}}</ref>
Some economists and left-wing academics including ] and ] argue that the economies of the former ] and Eastern bloc represented a form of state capitalism because their internal organization within enterprises and the system of wage labor remained intact.<ref>, M. C. Howard and J. E. King</ref><ref>] (1986). . ''Our Generation''. Retrieved 9 July 2015.</ref><ref>] (27 June 2015). . ''].'' Retrieved 9 July 2015.</ref>


This is a concept of capitalism described in ] and ]'s manifesto for the ] to describe a long-term political, economic and social structure which would mitigate current threats to the planet and society.<ref name="genfound">{{Cite web |last1=Gore |first1=Al |last2=Blood |first2=David |title=A Manifesto for Sustainable Capitalism |url=https://www.genfound.org/media/pdf-wsj-manifesto-sustainable-capitalism-14-12-11.pdf |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140124005644/https://www.genfound.org/media/pdf-wsj-manifesto-sustainable-capitalism-14-12-11.pdf |archive-date=24 January 2014 |access-date=24 October 2022 |website=Generation Foundation}}</ref> According to their manifesto, sustainable capitalism would integrate the environmental, social and governance (]) aspects into risk assessment in attempt to limit externalities.<ref name=":0b">{{Cite web|url=https://www.generationim.com/media/pdf-generation-sustainable-capitalism-v1.pdf |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221009/https://www.generationim.com/media/pdf-generation-sustainable-capitalism-v1.pdf |archive-date=9 October 2022 |url-status=live|title=Sustainable Capitalism|access-date=18 February 2017}}</ref> Most of the ideas they list are related to economic changes, and social aspects, but strikingly few are explicitly related to any environmental policy change.<ref name="genfound" />
The term is not used by Austrian school economists to describe state ownership of the means of production. The economist Ludwig von Mises argued that the designation of "state capitalism" was simply a new label for the old labels of "state socialism" and "planned economy", and differed only in non-essentials from these earlier designations.<ref>{{cite book|first = Ludwig|last = Von Mises|authorlink = Ludwig Von Mises|title = Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis|publisher = LibertyClassics|place = Indianapolis|year = 1979|isbn = 0-913966-63-0|url = https://www.mises.org/books/socialism/preface_second_german_edition.aspx|accessdate = 31 May 2007|quote="The socialist movement takes great pains to circulate frequently new labels for its ideally constructed state. Each worn-out label is replaced by another which raises hopes of an ultimate solution of the insoluble basic problem of Socialism – until it becomes obvious that nothing has been changed but the name. The most recent slogan is 'State Capitalism.' It is not commonly realized that this covers nothing more than what used to be called Planned Economy and State Socialism, and that State Capitalism, Planned Economy, and State Socialism diverge only in non-essentials from the "classic" ideal of egalitarian Socialism"}}</ref>


== Capital accumulation ==
The debate between proponents of private versus state capitalism is centered around questions of managerial efficacy, productive efficiency, and fair distribution of wealth.
{{Main|Capital accumulation}}

The accumulation of capital is the process of "making money" or growing an initial sum of money through investment in production. Capitalism is based on the accumulation of capital, whereby ] is invested in order to make a profit and then reinvested into further production in a continuous process of accumulation. In Marxian economic theory, this dynamic is called the ]. Capital accumulation forms the basis of capitalism, where economic activity is structured around the accumulation of ], defined as investment in order to realize a financial profit.<ref name="Economist definition">{{cite news | title = Economics A–Z: ''Capital'' | url = http://www.economist.com/economics-a-to-z/c#node-21529870 | website = ] | access-date = 25 March 2015 | archive-date = 7 August 2017 | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20170807235225/http://www.economist.com/economics-a-to-z/c#node-21529870 | url-status = live }}</ref> In this context, "capital" is defined as money or a financial asset invested for the purpose of making more money (whether in the form of profit, rent, interest, royalties, capital gain or some other kind of return).<ref name="MIA definition">{{cite web | title = Encyclopedia of Marxism – Glossary of terms: ''Capital'' | url = http://marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capital | website = ] | access-date = 25 March 2015 | archive-date = 18 June 2015 | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20150618083941/https://www.marxists.org/glossary/terms/c/a.htm#capital | url-status = live }}</ref>
=== Corporate capitalism ===
{{Main article|Corporate capitalism}}
{{See also|State monopoly capitalism|Crony capitalism}}
Corporate capitalism is a free or mixed-market economy characterized by the dominance of hierarchical, bureaucratic corporations.

=== Mixed economy ===
{{Main article|Mixed economy}}
{{See also|Economic interventionism}}
A mixed economy is a largely market-based economy consisting of both private and public ownership of the means of production and ] through macroeconomic policies intended to correct ]s, reduce unemployment and keep inflation low. The degree of intervention in markets varies among different countries. Some mixed economies, such as France under ], also featured a degree of ] over a largely capitalist-based economy.

Most modern capitalist economies are defined as "mixed economies" to some degree.{{Citation needed|date=September 2011}}

=== Racial capitalism ===
In her article "Racial Capitalism," Nancy Leong defines racial capitalism as "the process" that occurs when individuals or institutions profit "from the racial identity of another person."<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Leong|first=Nancy|year=2013|title=Racial Capitalism|url=|journal=Harvard Law Review|volume=126|page=2152|via=}}</ref>

=== Others ===
Other variants of capitalism include:{{Col-begin|width=100%}}
{{Col-1-of-3}}
* ]
* ]
* ]
{{Col-2-of-3}}
* ]
* ]
* ]
{{Col-3-of-3}}
* ]
{{col-end}}

== Role of government ==
{{Further information|Competition regulator|Consumer protection|Competition law}}
In a capitalist system, the government does not prohibit private property or prevent individuals from working where they please. The government does not prevent firms from determining what wages they will pay and what prices they will charge for their products. However, many countries have ] laws and minimum safety standards.

Under some versions of capitalism, the government carries out a number of economic functions, such as issuing money, supervising public utilities and enforcing private contracts. Many countries have ]s that prohibit monopolies and cartels from forming. Despite anti-monopoly laws, large corporations can form near-monopolies in some industries. Such firms can temporarily drop prices and accept losses to prevent competition from entering the market, and then raise them again once the threat of entry is reduced. In many countries, public utilities (e.g. electricity, heating fuel, communications) are able to operate as a monopoly under government regulation, due to high economies of scale.


In mainstream ], ] and ], capital accumulation is often equated with ] of profit income or savings, especially in ] capital goods. The concentration and centralisation of capital are two of the results of such accumulation. In modern ] and ], the phrase "]" is often used in preference to "accumulation", though the ] (UNCTAD) refers nowadays to "accumulation". The term "accumulation" is occasionally used in ].
Government agencies regulate the standards of service in many industries, such as airlines and broadcasting, as well as financing a wide range of programs. In addition, the government regulates the flow of capital and uses financial tools such as the interest rate to control factors such as inflation and unemployment.<ref>"Capitalism." World Book Encyclopedia. 1988. p. 194.</ref>


== Wage labor ==
=== Adverse characteristics of capitalist governments ===
{{Main|Wage labour}}
] argue that the role of the state in a capitalist society is to defend the interests of the ].<ref name=democraticsocialists>{{cite web|url=http://www.dsp.org.au/node/33|title=The role and character of the state under capitalism – Democratic Socialist Perspective|publisher=}}</ref> These governments take actions to implement such things as unified national markets, national currencies, and customs system.<ref name=democraticsocialists /> Capitalist governments have also been criticised as ] in nature<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.diffen.com/difference/Capitalism_vs_Socialism|title=Capitalism vs Socialism – Difference and Comparison – Diffen|publisher=}}</ref> due to the inevitable inequality<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/2013-02-11/capitalism-and-inequality|title=Capitalism and Inequality|date=15 September 2015|publisher=}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.newshub.co.nz/nznews/inequality-inevitable-under-capitalism---expert-2015012010|title=Inequality inevitable under capitalism – expert|publisher=}}</ref> characteristic of economic progress.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.academia.edu/2114498/Theories_of_Class_and_Social_Inequality|title=Theories of Class and Social Inequality|publisher=}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.pragcap.com/is-wealth-and-income-inequality-inevitable-in-a-capitalist-system|title=Is Wealth and Income Inequality Inevitable in a Capitalist System? – Pragmatic Capitalism|publisher=}}</ref>
], ], {{Circa|1995}}–2000)]]
Wage labor refers to the sale of ] under a formal or informal ] to an ].<ref name="Steinfeld 2009 3"/> These transactions usually occur in a ] where ]s are market determined.<ref>{{Harvnb|Deakin|Wilkinson|2005}}.<br />{{Harvnb|Marx|1990|p=1005}}, defines wage labour succinctly as "the labour of the worker who sells his own labour-power."</ref> In Marxist economics, these owners of the means of production and suppliers of capital are generally called capitalists. The description of the role of the capitalist has shifted, first referring to a useless intermediary between producers, then to an employer of producers, and finally to the owners of the means of production.<ref name="Williams 1983 51" /> ] includes all physical and mental human resources, including entrepreneurial capacity and management skills, which are required to produce products and services. ] is the act of making goods or services by applying ].<ref>Ragan, Christopher T.S.; Lipsey, Richard G. ''Microeconomics''. 12th Canadian ed. Toronto, Pearson Education, 2008. {{ISBN|978-0-321-31491-8}}</ref><ref>Robbins, Richard H. ''Global problems and the culture of capitalism''. Boston: Allyn & Bacon, 2007. {{ISBN|978-0-205-52487-7}}</ref>


== Criticism == == Criticism ==
{{Further information|Opposition to capitalism|Criticism of capitalism}} {{Main|Criticism of capitalism}}
] poster "]" (1911)]] ] poster "]" (1911)]]
Criticism of capitalism comes from various political and philosophical approaches, including ], ], ] and ] viewpoints.<ref>{{cite book|last=Tormey|first=Simon|title=Anticapitalism|publisher=One World Publications|year=2004|page=10|isbn=978-1-78074-250-2}}</ref> Of those who oppose it or want to modify it, some believe that capitalism should be removed through ] while others believe that it should be changed slowly through ].<ref>{{cite book|title=Book: Sociology (Boundless)|chapter=16.1C: The Marxist Critique of Capitalism|url=https://socialsci.libretexts.org/@go/page/8462|date=16 December 2020|publisher=LibreTexts|access-date=21 October 2021|quote=Revolutionary socialists believe that capitalism can only be overcome through revolution. Social democrats believe that structural change can come slowly through political reforms to capitalism.}}</ref><ref name="The Cambridge History of Communism p.">{{cite book | editor-last=Pons | editor-first=Silvio | editor-last2=Smith | editor-first2=Stephen A. | title=The Cambridge History of Communism | publisher=Cambridge University Press | date=21 September 2017 | isbn=978-1-316-13702-4 | doi=10.1017/9781316137024 | pages=49–73}}</ref>
Critics of capitalism associate the economic system with ]; unfair ] and power; ]; repression of workers and ]ists; ]; ]; ]; and economic instability.<ref>Korstanje, M (2015). Review: Why Nations fail. The origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty. Journal of International and Global Studies. Volume 6, issue 2. May 2015. (pp. 97–100.)</ref> Many socialists consider capitalism to be irrational, in that production and the direction of the economy are unplanned, creating many inconsistencies and internal contradictions.<ref>Korstanje, M (2015). A Difficult World, examining the roots of Capitalism. New York, Nova Science.</ref><ref>Brander, James A. ''Government policy toward business''. 4th {{abbr|ed.|edition}} Mississauga, Ontario, John Wiley & Sons Canada, 2006. Print.</ref> Capitalism and individual property rights have been associated with the ] where owners are unable to agree. ] ] postulates that capitalist economies prioritize profits and capital accumulation over the social needs of communities, and capitalist enterprises rarely include the workers in the basic decisions of the enterprise.<ref>Frances Goldin, Debby Smith, Michael Smith (2014). ''Imagine: Living in a Socialist USA.'' ]. {{ISBN|0-06-230557-3}} pp. 49–50.</ref>


Prominent critiques of capitalism allege that it is inherently ],<ref name="competition">{{cite web|url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1845/condition-working-class/ch05.htm|title=Competition – The Condition of the Working Class in England|last=Engels|first=Frederick|access-date=10 March 2008}}</ref><ref name="stanfordexploitation">{{Cite web|date=20 December 2001|title=Exploitation|url=https://plato.stanford.edu/entries/exploitation/|url-status=live|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201127091753/https://plato.stanford.edu/entries/exploitation/|archive-date=27 November 2020|access-date=26 December 2020|website=]}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Mattei|first=Clara E.|date=2022 |title=The Capital Order: How Economists Invented Austerity and Paved the Way to Fascism|pages=17–18|url=https://press.uchicago.edu/ucp/books/book/chicago/C/bo181707138.html|location= |publisher=]|isbn=978-0-226-81839-9}}</ref> ],<ref>"Alienation." Pp. 10. in ''A Dictionary of Philosophy'' (rev. 2nd ed.). 1984.</ref> ],<ref name="onfreetrade">{{cite web|url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1888/free-trade/index.htm|title=On the Question of Free Trade|last=Engels|first=Frederick|access-date=11 March 2008}}</ref><ref name="isrcrisis">{{cite web|url=http://www.isreview.org/issues/32/crisis_theory.shtml|title=Marx's Theory of Economic Crisis|last=Easterling|first=Earl|publisher=International Socialist Review|access-date=13 March 2008|archive-date=27 February 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210227033442/https://isreview.org/issues/32/crisis_theory.shtml|url-status=dead}}</ref> ],<ref name="extinction">{{cite book|last=Dawson|first=Ashley|author-link=Ashley Dawson|title=Extinction: A Radical History|date=2016|publisher=]|url=http://www.orbooks.com/catalog/extinction-by-ashley-dawson/|page=41|isbn=978-1-944869-01-4|access-date=20 August 2016|archive-date=17 September 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160917203814/http://www.orbooks.com/catalog/extinction-by-ashley-dawson/|url-status=live}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web |last=Nelson |first=Anitra |date=31 January 2024 |title=Degrowth as a Concept and Practice : Introduction |url=https://commonslibrary.org/degrowth-as-a-concept-and-practice-introduction/ |access-date=24 February 2024 |website=The Commons Social Change Library |language=en-AU}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title=Earth at risk: An urgent call to end the age of destruction and forge a just and sustainable future |journal=PNAS Nexus |date=4 April 2024 |volume=3 |issue=4 |doi=10.1093/pnasnexus/pgae106 |url=https://academic.oup.com/pnasnexus/article/3/4/pgae106/7638480?login=false |access-date=4 April 2024|pmc=10986754 |last1=Fletcher |first1=Charles |last2=Ripple |first2=William J. |last3=Newsome |first3=Thomas |last4=Barnard |first4=Phoebe |last5=Beamer |first5=Kamanamaikalani |last6=Behl |first6=Aishwarya |last7=Bowen |first7=Jay |last8=Cooney |first8=Michael |last9=Crist |first9=Eileen |last10=Field |first10=Christopher |last11=Hiser |first11=Krista |last12=Karl |first12=David M. |last13=King |first13=David A. |last14=Mann |first14=Michael E. |last15=McGregor |first15=Davianna P. |last16=Mora |first16=Camilo |last17=Oreskes |first17=Naomi |last18=Wilson |first18=Michael |pages=pgae106 |pmid=38566756 }}</ref> and ]<ref>{{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=BlEpAQAAMAAJ|title=Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for a post-capitalist era|last=Shutt|first=Harry|date=March 2010|publisher=Zed Books|isbn=978-1-84813-417-1}}</ref><ref name="isrwaste">{{cite web|url=http://www.isreview.org/issues/53/garbage.shtml|title=The Conquest of Garbage|last=Rogers|first=Heather|website=isreview.org|publisher=International Socialist Review (1997)|access-date=13 March 2008|archive-date=10 May 2021|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20210510142346/http://www.isreview.org/issues/53/garbage.shtml|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref name="part6">{{cite web|url=http://www.chass.utoronto.ca/~reak/eco100/100_6.htm|title=Monopoly, Imperfect Competition, and Oligopoly|last=Rea|first=K.J.|access-date=11 March 2008|archive-date=12 June 2010|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100612201706/http://www.chass.utoronto.ca/~reak/eco100/100_6.htm|url-status=dead}}</ref>—and that it creates massive ],<ref name="King 2021">{{cite web|last=King|first=Matthew Wilburn|title=Why the next stage of capitalism is coming|website=BBC Future|date=25 May 2021|url=https://www.bbc.com/future/article/20210525-why-the-next-stage-of-capitalism-is-coming|access-date=21 October 2021}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Ghodsee|first1=Kristen|last2=Orenstein|first2=Mitchell A.|author-link1=Kristen Ghodsee|date=2021|title=Taking Stock of Shock: Social Consequences of the 1989 Revolutions|publisher=]|page=192|doi=10.1093/oso/9780197549230.001.0001 |isbn=978-0-19-754924-7|quote=Without an accompanying welfare state in which social programs funded by a progressive income tax redistribute from the rich to the poor, capitalism can be a deeply unfair system where a small, well-connected elite captures a majority of the wealth and power, and not necessarily through meritocratic processes.}}</ref> ] people,<ref name="openDemocracy">{{cite web | title=Commodification: the essence of our time | website=openDemocracy | url=https://www.opendemocracy.net/en/opendemocracyuk/commodification-essence-of-our-time/ | access-date=21 October 2021 | author= Colin Leys | date = 2 April 2021}}</ref><ref name="Renegade Inc 2019">{{cite web | title=The Commodification of Everything | website=Renegade Inc | date=25 August 2019 | url=http://renegadeinc.com/the-commodification-of-everything/ | access-date=21 October 2021 | author=Daniel Margrain | archive-date=21 October 2021 | archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20211021224916/https://renegadeinc.com/the-commodification-of-everything/ | url-status=dead }}</ref> ],<ref name="extinction" /><ref>{{cite book|last=Hickel|first=Jason|author-link=Jason Hickel|title=Less is More: How Degrowth Will Save the World |year=2021|publisher=Windmill Books|pages=39–40|isbn=978-1-78609-121-5|quote=It was only with the rise of capitalism over the past few hundred years, and the breathtaking acceleration of industrialization from the 1950s, that on a planetary scale things began to tip out of balance.}}</ref> is ],<ref name="Merkel pp. 109–128">{{cite journal | last=Merkel | first=Wolfgang | title=Is capitalism compatible with democracy? | journal=Zeitschrift für Vergleichende Politikwissenschaft | publisher=Springer Science and Business Media LLC | volume=8 | issue=2 | date=26 July 2014 | issn=1865-2646 | doi=10.1007/s12286-014-0199-4 | pages=109–128| hdl=10419/270951 | s2cid=150776013 | hdl-access=free }}</ref><ref name="Reich 2009">{{cite web | last=Reich | first=Robert B. | title=How Capitalism Is Killing Democracy | website=Foreign Policy | date=12 October 2009 | url=https://foreignpolicy.com/2009/10/12/how-capitalism-is-killing-democracy/ | access-date=21 October 2021}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Slobodian|first=Quinn |author-link=Quinn Slobodian|date=2023 |title=Crack-Up Capitalism: Market Radicals and the Dream of a World Without Democracy|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=tIlrEAAAQBAJ&pg=PT10|location= |publisher=]|page=10 |isbn=978-1-250-75389-2}}
Some ] and scholars have argued that ]{{snd}}by ], ]s, ] or other coerced persons{{snd}}is compatible with capitalist relations. ] argued that unfree labor is acceptable to capital.<ref>Cass, ''Towards a Comparative Political Economy of Unfree Labor'' (1999)</ref><ref>{{cite journal|url=http://www.historycooperative.org/journals/llt/52/linden.html |title=Labour History as the History of Multitudes |journal=Labour / Le Travail |volume=52 |date=Fall 2003 |pages=235–44 |author=Marcel van der Linden |accessdate=26 February 2008 |doi=10.2307/25149390 |jstor=25149390 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20071217185826/http://www.historycooperative.org/journals/llt/52/linden.html |archivedate=17 December 2007 |df=dmy }}</ref> Historian ] argues that capitalism has its origins in slavery: "when historians talk about the Atlantic market revolution, they are talking about capitalism. And when they are talking about capitalism, they are talking about slavery."<ref name="Grandin">, '']'' (August 2014). Retrieved 4 August 2014.</ref> Historian ] claims that slavery was an integral component in the violent development of American and global capitalism.<ref>Edward E. Baptist. ''.'' ], September 2014. {{ISBN|0-465-00296-X}}.</ref>
</ref> embeds ] and ] between nation states,<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Patnaik |first1=Utsa |title='Neo-Marxian' Theories of Capitalism and Underdevelopment: Towards a Critique |journal=Social Scientist |date=1982 |volume=10 |issue=11 |pages=3–32 |doi=10.2307/3516858 |jstor=3516858 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/3516858 |issn=0970-0293}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Warke |first1=Thomas W. |title=The Marxian Theory of Underdevelopment: A Review Article |journal=The Journal of Developing Areas |date=1973 |volume=7 |issue=4 |pages=699–710 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/4190085#:~:text=it%20is%20Lenin%20who%20laid,modern%20Marxian%20theory%20of%20underdevelopment.&text=and%20tends%20to%20perpetuate%20the,masses%20in%20the%20backward%20country.&text=world%20production%20and%20trade%20and,dualisms%20within%20under%2D%20developed%20economies. |issn=0022-037X}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Martins |first1=Carlos Eduardo |title=The Longue Durée of the Marxist Theory of Dependency and the Twenty-First Century |journal=Latin American Perspectives |date=January 2022 |volume=49 |issue=1 |pages=18–35 |doi=10.1177/0094582X211052029 |url=https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/0094582X211052029 |language=en |issn=0094-582X}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Peck |first1=Jamie |last2=Varadarajan |first2=Latha |title=Uneven Regional Development |journal=International Encyclopedia of Geography: People, the Earth, Environment and Technology |date=6 March 2017 |pages=1–13 |doi=10.1002/9781118786352.wbieg0721 |url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1002/9781118786352.wbieg0721 |publisher=John Wiley & Sons, Ltd |isbn=9780470659632 |language=en}}</ref> and leads to an erosion of ]<ref>{{cite journal|last=Abeles|first=Marc|date=2006|title=Globalization, Power, and Survival: an Anthropological Perspective|url=https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00125880/file/M_Abeles_2006_AQ.pdf |archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/archive/20221009/https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-00125880/file/M_Abeles_2006_AQ.pdf |archive-date=9 October 2022 |url-status=live|journal=Anthropological Quarterly|volume=79|issue=3|pages=484–486|doi=10.1353/anq.2006.0030|s2cid=144220354}}</ref> because of its ] of ] expansion and ].<ref>{{cite journal|last=Farid|first=Hilmar|date=2005|title=Indonesia's original sin: mass killings and capitalist expansion, 1965–66|journal=]|volume=6|issue=1|pages=3–16|doi=10.1080/1462394042000326879|s2cid=145130614}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|last=Blakeley|first=Ruth|date=2009|title=State Terrorism and Neoliberalism: The North in the South|url=http://www.routledge.com/books/details/9780415462402/|publisher=]|pages=, , |isbn=978-0-415-68617-4}}</ref><ref>''Lenin's Selected Works'', Progress Publishers, 1963, Moscow, Volume 1, pp. 667–766</ref>


Other critics argue that such inequities are not due to the ethic-neutral construct of the economic system commonly known as capitalism, but to the ethics of those who shape and execute the system. For example, some contend that Milton Friedman's (human) ethic of 'maximizing shareholder value' creates a harmful form of capitalism,<ref>{{Cite book |last=Stout |first=Lynn |author-link=Lynn Stout |title=The Shareholder Value Myth |publisher=Berrett-Koehler Publishers, Inc. |year=2012 |isbn=978-1-60509-813-5 |location=San Francisco, CA |pages=15–23}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book |last=Gelles |first=David |author-link=David Gelles |title=The Man Who Broke Capitalism |publisher=Simon & Schuster |year=2022 |isbn=978-1-9821-7644-0 |location=New York |pages=1–13}}</ref> while a ] or John Bogle (human) ethic of 'enough' creates a sustainable form.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Fuller |first=Millard |author-link=Millard Fuller|title=The Theology of the Hammer |publisher=Smyth & Helwys Publishing |year=1994 |isbn=1-880837-92-7 |location=Macon, GA |pages=31–39}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book |last=Bogle |first=John |title=Enough |publisher=John Wiley & Sons |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-470-52423-7 |location=Hoboken, New Jersey |pages=229–248}}</ref> Equitable ethics and unified ethical decision-making is theorized to create a less damaging form of capitalism.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Knowlton & Hedges |title=Better Capitalism |publisher=Wipf & Stock Publishers |year=2021 |isbn=978-1-7252-8093-9 |location=Eugene, OR |pages=34–37, 235–242}}</ref>
According to ], institutional racism has been "one of the most significant pillars" of the capitalist system and serves as "the ideological justification for the hierarchization of the work-force and its highly unequal distributions of reward".<ref>{{cite book | last = Wallerstein| first = Immanuel | authorlink = Immanuel Wallerstein | title = Historical Capitalism | publisher= ] | year = 1983 | isbn = 0-86091-761-4 | page = 78}}</ref>


] has been argued to not be a fundamental part of capitalism,<ref name="x107">{{cite journal | last=Haslett | first=D. W. | title=Is Inheritance Justified? | journal=Philosophy & Public Affairs | publisher=Wiley | volume=15 | issue=2 | year=1986 | issn=0048-3915 | jstor=2265382 | pages=122–155 | url=http://www.jstor.org/stable/2265382 | access-date=17 August 2024}}</ref> instead part of ].<ref name="e543">{{cite journal | last=Pérez-González | first=Francisco | title=Inherited Control and Firm Performance | journal=American Economic Review | volume=96 | issue=5 | date=1 November 2006 | issn=0002-8282 | doi=10.1257/aer.96.5.1559 | pages=1559–1588}}</ref>
Many aspects of capitalism have come under attack from the ], which is primarily opposed to ]. ] have argued that capitalism requires continual economic growth, and that it will inevitably deplete the finite natural resources of Earth and cause ] of animal and plant life.<ref name="McMurty 1999" /><ref>George Monbiot (1 October 2014). . ''].'' Retrieved 31 October 2014.</ref><ref>{{cite book|last=Dawson|first=Ashley|authorlink =Ashley Dawson |title=Extinction: A Radical History|date=2016|publisher=]|url=http://www.orbooks.com/catalog/extinction-by-ashley-dawson/ |isbn=978-1-944869-01-4}}</ref> Such critics argue that, while this ] or contemporary capitalism has indeed increased global trade, it has also destroyed traditional ways of life, exacerbated inequality and increased global ]{{snd}}with more living today in abject poverty than before neoliberalism, and that environmental indicators indicate massive ] since the late 1970s.<ref name="Duménil">. ''].'' 30 March 2010. Retrieved 3 January 2014.
* "When we speak of neoliberalism, we speak of contemporary capitalism."{{snd}}], former Research Director at the Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique (CNRS)</ref><ref>Jones, Campbell, Martin Parker and Rene Ten Bos, ''For Business Ethics''. (], 2005) {{ISBN|0-415-31135-7}}, p. 101.</ref><ref>. ''Business Insider''. May 2016.</ref>

Some scholars blame the ] on the neoliberal capitalist model.{{refn|<ref>{{cite journal |last=Lavoie |first=Marc |title=Financialization, neo-liberalism, and securitization |journal=Journal of Post Keynesian Economics |volume=35 |issue=2 |pages=215–33 |jstor=23469991 |date=Winter 2012–2013 |subscription=yes |doi=10.2753/pke0160-3477350203}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last= Stein|first=Howard|last2= |first2= |date=25 July 2012|title=The Neoliberal Policy Paradigm and the Great Recession|url=http://www.panoeconomicus.rs/casopis/2012_4/02%20Howard%20Stein.pdf|journal=Panoeconomicus|volume=59 |issue= 4|pages= 421–40|doi=10.2298/PAN1204421S|access-date=4 June 2017|quote= "The role of deregulation and related neoliberal policies as a both a source of massive financialization of the economy and cause of the Great Recession is widely recognized in the literature (David M. Kotz 2009; Bill Lucarelli 2009; Joseph Stiglitz 2010; William Tabb 2012). Some authors aptly call it the “crisis of neoliberal capitalism” (Kotz 2010)."}}</ref><ref>Susan Braedley and Meg Luxton, '''' (], 2010), {{ISBN|0-7735-3692-2}}, </ref><ref>] and Ravi K. Roy. ''''. (], 2010.) {{ISBN|0-19-956051-X}}. p. 123.</ref><ref>Gérard Duménil and Dominique Lévy, ''.'' (], 2013), {{ISBN|0-674-07224-3}}</ref><ref>David M Kotz, '''' (], 2015), {{ISBN|0-674-72565-4}}</ref>}} Following the banking crisis of 2007, ] told the United States Congress on 23 October 2008: "The whole intellectual edifice collapsed. I made a mistake in presuming that the self-interests of organizations, specifically banks and others, were such that they were best capable of protecting their own shareholders. ... I was shocked."<ref>New York Times, 23 October 2007.</ref>

Many religions have criticized or opposed specific elements of capitalism. Traditional ], ], and Islam forbid ],<ref>'']'' 61b</ref><ref>Moehlman, 1934, pp. 6–7.</ref> although alternative methods of banking have been developed. Some Christians have criticized capitalism for its ] aspects and its inability to account for the wellbeing of all people.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.vatican.va/archive/ENG0015/__P8C.HTM#-2FX |title=III. The Social Doctrine of the Church |publisher=The Vatican |accessdate=26 February 2008 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20080219151222/http://www.vatican.va/archive/ENG0015/__P8C.HTM |archivedate=19 February 2008 |df=dmy }}</ref> Many of Jesus' parables deal with economic concerns: farming, shepherding, being in debt, doing hard labor, being excluded from banquets and the houses of the rich, and have implications for wealth and power distribution.<ref>{{cite news |last=]|title=What Jesus said about capitalism|url=http://www.smh.com.au/business/what-jesus-said-about-capitalism-20120408-1wjmm.html|accessdate=28 April 2012|newspaper=The Sydney Morning Herald|date=9 April 2012}}</ref><ref>Thomas Gubleton, archbishop of Detroit speaking in '']''</ref> Catholic scholars and clergy have often criticized capitalism because of its disenfranchisement of the poor often promoting ] as an alternative. In his 84-page ] ''],'' ] ] described unfettered capitalism as "a new tyranny" and called on world leaders to fight rising poverty and inequality:<ref>. ] (November 2013). Retrieved 30 December 2013.</ref>

<blockquote>Some people continue to defend ] which assume that economic growth, encouraged by a free market, will inevitably succeed in bringing about greater justice and inclusiveness in the world. This opinion, which has never been confirmed by the facts, expresses a crude and naive trust in the goodness of those wielding economic power and in the sacralized workings of the prevailing economic system. Meanwhile, the excluded are still waiting.<ref>Zachary A. Goldfarb and Michelle Boorstein (26 November 2013). . ''].'' Retrieved 26 November 2013.</ref></blockquote>

Proponents of capitalism argue that it creates more prosperity than any other economic system, and that its benefits are mainly to the ordinary person.<ref>Friedman, Milton. ''Capitalism and Freedom''. University of Chicago, 1962.</ref> Critics of capitalism variously associate it with economic instability,<ref>Krugman, Paul, Wells, Robin, ''Economics'', Worth Publishers, New York (2006)</ref> an inability to provide for the well-being of all people,<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.vatican.va/holy_father/benedict_xvi/encyclicals/documents/hf_ben-xvi_enc_20090629_caritas-in-veritate_en.html|title=Caritas in veritate paragraph 36|accessdate=7 October 2014}}</ref> and an unsustainable danger to the natural environment.<ref name="McMurty 1999">{{cite book |last = McMurty |first = John |title = The Cancer Stage of Capitalism |publisher = Pluto Press |year = 1999 |isbn = 0-7453-1347-7}}</ref> ] maintain that, although capitalism is superior to all previously existing economic systems (such as feudalism or slavery), the contradiction between class interests will only be resolved by advancing into a completely new social system of production and distribution in which all persons have an equal relationship to the means of production.<ref>''The Rise of Capitalism'', 2011. Socialist Standard, no. 1284, August 2011.</ref>

The term capitalism in its modern sense is often attributed to ].<ref name="Scott">{{cite book |title=Industrialism: A Dictionary of Sociology|author=Scott, John|publisher=Oxford University Press|year=2005}}</ref><ref>{{cite web |title="capitalism, n.2". OED Online|url=http://www.oed.com/view/Entry/27454?rskey=ZVI1hr&result=2&isAdvanced=false}}</ref> In his ] '']'', Marx analysed the "]" using a method of understanding today known as ]. However, Marx himself rarely used the term "capitalism", while it was used twice in the more political interpretations of his work, primarily authored by his collaborator ]. In the 20th century, defenders of the capitalist system often replaced the term ''capitalism'' with phrases such as ''free enterprise'' and ''private enterprise'' and replaced ''capitalist'' with '']'' and '']'' in reaction to the negative connotations associated with capitalism.<ref name="Williams 1983 51">{{cite book |last= Williams|first= Raymond |title= Keywords: A vocabulary of culture and society, revised edition|publisher= Oxford University Press|year= 1983|month= |isbn= 0-19-520469-7|page = 51|chapter= Capitalism}}</ref>

=== Profit motive ===
The majority of criticisms against the profit motive centre on the idea that profits should not supersede the needs of people. ]'s film '']'', for example, attacks the healthcare industry for its alleged emphasis on profits at the expense of patients.<ref>"Press Room." Michaelmoore.com. {{clarify|date=March 2016}} Michael Moore. Web. 22 April 2013.</ref> Moore explains:

:We should have no talk of profit when it comes to helping people who are sick. The profit motive should be nowhere involved in this. And you know what? It's not fair to the insurance companies either because they have a fiduciary responsibility to make as much money as they can for their shareholders. Well, the way they make more money is to deny claims or to kick people off the rolls or to not even let people on the rolls because they have a pre-existing condition. You know, all of that is wrong.<ref>Ballasy, Nicholas. "Michael Moore: ‘It's Absolutely a Good Thing’ for Government to Drive Private Health Insurance Out of Business." Michael Moore: 'It's Absolutely a Good Thing' for Government to Drive Private Health Insurance Out of Business. CNS News, 2 October 2009. Web. 22 April 2013.</ref>

Another common criticism of the profit motive is that it is believed to encourage selfishness and greed. Critics of the profit motive contend that companies disregard morals or public safety in the pursuit of profits.<ref>"'Occupy Wall Street' Protests Give Voice to Anger Over Greed, Corporate Culture." PBS.com, 5 October 2011. Web. 22 April 2013.</ref>

] economists counter that the profit motive, coupled with competition, actually reduces the final price of an item for consumption, rather than raising it. They argue that businesses profit by selling a good at a lower price and at a greater volume than the competition. Economist ] uses supermarkets as an example to illustrate this point: “It has been estimated that a supermarket makes a clear profit of about a penny on a dollar of sales. If that sounds pretty skimpy, remember that it is collecting that penny on every dollar at several cash registers simultaneously and, in many cases, around the clock.”<ref>Sowell, Thomas. "Profit Motive Underrated By Intelligentsia." ''Sun-Sentinel'', 26 December 2003. Web. 22 April 2013.</ref>

U.S. economist ] has argued that greed and self-interest are ]. On a 1979 episode of ], Friedman states: “The world runs on individuals pursuing their separate interests.” He continues by explaining that only in capitalist countries, where individuals can pursue their own self-interest, people have been able to escape from “grinding poverty”.<ref>Pantin, Travis. "Milton Friedman Answers Phil Donahue's Charges". ''The New York Sun'', 12 November 2007. Web. 22 April 2013.</ref>

=== Marxian responses ===
{{Main article|Marxian economics}}
{{Marxian economics}}
Marx considered capitalism to be a historically specific ] (the way in which the productive property is owned and controlled, combined with the corresponding ] between individuals based on their connection with the process of production).<ref name="Burnham"/>

The capitalist stage of development or "] society", for Marx, represented the most advanced form of social organization to date, but he also thought that the working classes would come to power in a worldwide ] or ] transformation of human society as the end of the series of first aristocratic, then capitalist, and finally working class rule was reached.<ref>'']''</ref><ref>"To Marx, the problem of reconstituting society did not arise from some prescription, motivated by his personal predilections; it followed, as an iron-clad historical necessity – on the one hand, from the productive forces grown to powerful maturity; on the other, from the impossibility further to organize these forces according to the will of the ]." – ], "Marxism in our Time", 1939 (Inevitability of Socialism), </ref>

Following ], Marx distinguished the ] of commodities from their ] in the market. Capital, according to Marx, is created with the purchase of commodities for the purpose of creating new commodities with an exchange value higher than the sum of the original purchases. For Marx, the use of ] had itself become a commodity under capitalism; the exchange value of labor power, as reflected in the wage, is less than the value it produces for the capitalist.

This difference in values, he argues, constitutes ], which the capitalists extract and accumulate. In his book '']'', Marx argues that the ] is distinguished by how the owners of capital extract this surplus from workers{{snd}}all prior class societies had extracted ], but capitalism was new in doing so via the sale-value of produced commodities.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1894-c3/ch47.htm|title=Capital. V. 3. Chapter 47: Genesis of capitalist ground rent|author=Karl Marx |accessdate=26 February 2008|publisher=Marxists }}</ref> He argues that a core requirement of a capitalist society is that a large portion of the population must not possess sources of self-sustenance that would allow them to be independent, and are instead forced to sell their labor for a wage.<ref>Karl Marx. Chapter Twenty-Five: The General Law of Capitalist Accumulation. '']''.</ref><ref>Dobb, Maurice, 1947. ''Studies in the Development of Capitalism''. New York, International Publishers Co.</ref><ref>David Harvey 1989 ''The Condition of Postmodernity''</ref>

In conjunction with his criticism of capitalism was Marx's belief that the working class, due to its relationship to the means of production and numerical superiority under capitalism, would be the driving force behind the socialist revolution.<ref>Wheen, Francis. ''Books That Shook the World: Marx's Das Kapital'' • 1st {{abbr|ed.|ediition}}, London, Atlantic Books, 2006.</ref> This argument is intertwined with Marx' version of the ] arguing that labor is the source of all value, and thus of profit.

], in '']'' (1916), further developed Marxist theory and argued that capitalism necessarily led to ] and the export of capital{{snd}}which he also called "imperialism"{{snd}}to find new markets and resources, representing the last and highest stage of capitalism.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1916/imp-hsc/index.htm|title=Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism|publisher=Marxists|accessdate=26 February 2008|year=1916}}</ref> Some 20th-century ] consider capitalism to be a social formation where capitalist class processes dominate, but are not exclusive.<ref>See, for example, the works of Stephen Resnick and Richard Wolff.</ref>

Capitalist class processes, to these thinkers, are simply those in which ] takes the form of ], usable as capital; other tendencies for utilization of labor nonetheless exist simultaneously in existing societies where capitalist processes predominate. However, other late Marxian thinkers argue that a social formation as a whole may be classed as capitalist if capitalism is the mode by which a surplus is ''extracted'', even if this surplus is not ''produced'' by capitalist activity, as when an absolute majority of the population is engaged in non-capitalist economic activity.<ref>{{cite book |author1=Ste. Croix |author2=G. E. M. de |title=The Class Struggle in the Ancient Greek World|year=1982|pages=52–53}}</ref>

In ''Limits to Capital'' (1982), ] outlines an overdetermined, "spatially restless" capitalism coupled with the spatiality of crisis formation and resolution.<ref>]. ''The Limits to Capital''. ], 17 January 2007. {{ISBN|1-84467-095-3}}</ref> Harvey used Marx's theory of crisis to aid his argument that capitalism must have its "fixes" but that we cannot predetermine what fixes will be implemented, nor in what form they will be. His work on contractions of capital accumulation and international movements of capitalist modes of production and money flows has been influential.<ref name="Lawson, Victoria 2007">Lawson, Victoria. Making Development Geography (Human Geography in the Making). New York: A Hodder Arnold Publication, 2007. Print.</ref> According to Harvey, capitalism creates the conditions for volatile and geographically uneven development <ref>Harvey, David. ''Notes towards a theory of uneven geographical development''. Print.</ref>

Sociologists such as Ulrich Beck envisioned the society of risk as a new cultural value which saw risk as a commodity to be exchanged in globalized economies. This theory suggested that disasters and capitalist economy were inevitably entwined. Disasters allow the introduction of economic programs which otherwise would be rejected, as well as decentralizing the class structure in production.<ref>Beck, U. (1992). Risk society: Towards a new modernity (Vol. 17). Sage.</ref> However, Philosopher Maximiliano Korstanje coined the term Thana-Capitalism to refer to a climate of social Darwinism aimed at fostering the "Survival of the Strongest". In this climate of struggle, only a few win while the rest lose. Social Darwinism is seen as a metaphor explaining our obsession with consumer news and with images related to terrorism attacks, trauma-scapes, and disasters. Korstanje writes that the society of risk has gradually set the pace to a new society of Thana-Capitalism, where the main commodity is death. Not only do we consume death everywhere in the entertainment industry, newspapers, and media but in so doing we reinforce our superiority by witnessing the suffering of others. Korstanje sees the story of Noah's Ark as an allegory for what he dubbed the first genocide. In this mythical event, God divided the world in two parts, the victims and the witnesses. This logic of the supremacy of those who live over those who die is reinforced by Christ´s crucifixion. Today, new emergent segments in the tourist industry are oriented to travel to places where mass deaths or traumatic event have occurred. Korstanje suggests that in secularized societies death is a sign of weakness, and consuming the deaths of others revitalizes the hopes of visitors to enter “the hall of chosen peoples".<ref>Korstanje M. E (2016) The Rise of Thana Capitalism and Tourism, Abingdon, Routledge.</ref><ref>Korstanje M E & George B (2016) “Craving for the consumption of suffering and Commoditization of Death: the evolving facet of Thana Capitalism”. In Terrorism in the Global Village: how terrorism affects our lives. Korstanje M (ed), Chapter 4. New York, Nova Science Publishers. URL https://www.novapublishers.com/catalog/product_info.php?products_id=59949&osCsid=</ref>

=== Supply and demand ===
At least two assumptions are necessary for the validity of the standard model: first, that supply and demand are independent; second, that supply is "constrained by a fixed resource". If these conditions do not hold, then the ] model cannot be sustained. ] critique focused on the inconsistency (except in implausible circumstances) of partial equilibrium analysis and the rationale for the upward slope of the supply curve in a market for a produced consumption good.<ref>Avi J. Cohen, "'The Laws of Returns Under Competitive Conditions': Progress in Microeconomics Since Sraffa (1926)?", ''Eastern Economic Journal'', {{abbr|vol.|volume}} 9, no. 3 (Jul.-Sep.): 1983)</ref> The notability of Sraffa's critique is also demonstrated by ]'s comments and engagements with it over many years, for example:

:"What a cleaned-up version of Sraffa (1926) establishes is how ''nearly empty'' are ''all'' of Marshall's partial equilibrium boxes. To a logical purist of Wittgenstein and Sraffa class, the ''Marshallian partial'' equilibrium box of ''constant'' cost is even more empty than the box of ''increasing'' cost."<ref>Paul A. Samuelson, "Reply" in ''Critical Essays on Piero Sraffa's Legacy in Economics'' (edited by H. D. Kurz), Cambridge University Press, 2000</ref>

Aggregate excess demand in a market is the difference between the quantity demanded and the quantity supplied as a function of price. In the model with an upward-sloping supply curve and downward-sloping demand curve, the aggregate excess demand function only intersects the axis at one point, namely, at the point where the supply and demand curves intersect. The ] shows that the standard model cannot be rigorously derived in general from ].<ref>Alan Kirman, "The Intrinsic Limits of Modern Economic Theory: The Emperor has No Clothes", ''The Economic Journal'', {{abbr|vol.|volume}} 99, no. 395, Supplement: Conference Papers (1989): pp. 126–39</ref>

The model of prices being determined by supply and demand assumes ]. But:
:"economists have no adequate model of how individuals and firms adjust prices in a competitive model. If all participants are price-takers by definition, then the actor who adjusts prices to eliminate excess demand is not specified".<ref>Alan P. Kirman, "Whom or What Does the Representative Individual Represent?" ''Journal of Economic Perspectives'', {{abbr|vol.|volume}} 6, no. 2 (Spring 1992): pp. 117–36</ref>

Goodwin, Nelson, Ackerman, and Weisskopf write:

:"If we mistakenly confuse ], then we might be misled into thinking that an explanation expressed in precise mathematical or graphical terms is somehow more rigorous or useful than one that takes into account particulars of history, institutions or business strategy. This is not the case. Therefore, it is important not to put too much confidence in the apparent precision of supply and demand graphs. Supply and demand analysis is a useful precisely formulated conceptual tool that clever people have devised to help us gain an abstract understanding of a complex world. It does not – nor should it be expected to – give us in addition an accurate and complete description of any particular real world market."<ref>Goodwin, N, Nelson, J; Ackerman, F; & Weisskopf, T: Microeconomics in Context 2d {{abbr|ed.|edition}} Sharpe 2009 {{ISBN|978-0-7656-2301-0}}</ref>

=== Counter-criticisms ===
==== Austrian School ====
Austrian School economists have argued that capitalism can organise itself into a complex system without an external guidance or central planning mechanism. Friedrich Hayek considered the phenomenon of ] as underpinning capitalism. Prices serve as a signal as to the urgent and unfilled wants of people, and the opportunity to earn profits if successful, or absorb losses if resources are used poorly or left idle, gives entrepreneurs ] to use their ] and resources to satisfy those wants. Thus the activities of millions of people, each seeking his own interest, are coordinated.<ref name=walberg2003>{{cite book |author=Walberg, Herbert |title=Education and Capitalism |url=http://www.hoover.org/publications/books/8328 |publisher=Hoover Institution Press |year=2003 |chapter=4, What is Capitalism? |pages=87–89 |isbn=0-8179-3972-5}}</ref>

==== Ayn Rand ====
The novelist and philosopher ] made positive moral defenses of ''laissez-faire'' capitalism, most notably in her 1957 novel '']'', and in her 1966 collection of essays '']''. She argued that capitalism should be supported on moral grounds, not just on the basis of practical benefits.<ref>{{cite book |first=Jennifer |last=Burns |chapter=Godless Capitalism: Ayn Rand and the Conservative Movement |title=American Capitalism: Social Thought and Political Economy in the Twentieth Century |editor-first=Nelson |editor-last=Lichtenstein |location=Philadelphia |publisher=University of Pennsylvania Press |year=2006 |isbn=978-0-8122-3923-2 |pages=282–83}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |first1=Douglas |last1=Den Uyl |last2=Rasmussen |first2=Douglas |chapter=Capitalism |title=] |editor1-last=Den Uyl |editor1-first=Douglas |editor2-last=Rasmussen |editor2-first=Douglas |authorlink2=Douglas B. Rasmussen |location=Chicago |publisher=University of Illinois Press |year=1984 |isbn=0-252-01033-7 |oclc=9392804 |lastauthoramp=y |pages=173–74}}</ref> Her ideas have had significant influence over conservative and ] supporters of capitalism, especially within the American ].<ref>{{cite book |title=Ayn Rand Nation: The Hidden Struggle for America's Soul |last=Weiss |first=Gary |authorlink=Gary Weiss |location=New York |publisher=St. Martin's Press |year=2012 |isbn=978-0-312-59073-4 |oclc=740628885 |pages=14–16}}</ref> Rand defined capitalism as "a social system based on the recognition of individual rights, including property rights, in which all property is privately owned."<ref>Ayn Rand, “What Is Capitalism?” Capitalism: The Unknown Ideal, 19</ref> According to Rand, the role of government in a capitalist state has three broad categories of proper functions: First, the police "to protect men from criminals". Second, the armed services "to protect men from foreign invaders". Third, the law courts "to settle disputes among men according to objective laws".<ref>Ayn Rand,"Nature of Government", Virtue of selfishness.</ref>

=== Economic growth ===
] per capita shows exponential growth since the beginning of the Industrial Revolution<ref>{{cite book |title=The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective |author=Angus Maddison |publisher=] |location=Paris |year=2001 |isbn=92-64-18998-X}}</ref>]]
]
Many theorists and policymakers in predominantly capitalist nations have emphasized capitalism's ability to promote economic growth, as measured by ] (GDP), ] or ]. This argument was central, for example, to Adam Smith's advocacy of letting a free market control production and price, and allocate resources. Many theorists have noted that this increase in global GDP over time coincides with the emergence of the modern world capitalist system.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.minneapolisfed.org/pubs/region/04-05/essay.cfm |title=The Industrial Revolution: Past and Future |author=Robert E. Lucas Jr. |work=Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 2003 Annual Report |accessdate=26 February 2008 |deadurl=yes |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20071127032512/http://minneapolisfed.org/pubs/region/04-05/essay.cfm |archivedate=27 November 2007 |df=dmy }}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.j-bradford-delong.net/TCEH/1998_Draft/World_GDP/Estimating_World_GDP.html |title=Estimating World GDP, One Million B.C. – Present |author=J. Bradford DeLong |accessdate=26 February 2008 }}</ref>

Between 1000 and 1820, the world economy grew sixfold, a faster rate than the population growth, so individuals enjoyed, on average, a 50% increase in income. Between 1820 and 1998, world economy grew 50-fold, a much faster rate than the population growth, so individuals enjoyed, on average, a 9-fold increase in income.<ref name="wolf44" /> In most capitalist economic regions such as Europe, the United States, Canada, Australia and New Zealand, the economy grew 19-fold per person, even though these countries already had a higher starting level, and in Japan, which was poor in 1820, the increase per person was 31-fold. In the ] there was an increase, but only 5-fold per person.<ref name="wolf44">], ''Why Globalization works'', pp.&nbsp;43–45</ref>

== Economic freedom ==
In his book '']'', ] asserts that the ] of capitalism is a requisite of ]. He argues that the market mechanism is the only way of deciding what to produce and how to distribute the items without using coercion. ], ] and ] also promoted this view. Friedman claimed that centralized economic operations are always accompanied by ]. In his view, transactions in a market economy are voluntary, and that the wide diversity that voluntary activity permits is a fundamental threat to repressive political leaders and greatly diminish their power to coerce. Some of Friedman's views were shared by ], who believed that capitalism is vital for freedom to survive and thrive.<ref>{{cite book |author=Friedrich Hayek|title=The Road to Serfdom|publisher=] |year=1944|isbn=0-226-32061-8}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |author=Bellamy, Richard|title=The Cambridge History of Twentieth-Century Political Thought|publisher=Cambridge University Press|year=2003|isbn=0-521-56354-2|page=60}}</ref> ], an American think tank that conducts international research on, and advocates for, democracy, political freedom, and human rights, has argued "there is a high and statistically significant correlation between the level of political freedom ] and economic freedom ]."<ref>Adrian Karatnycky. ''Freedom in the World: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties''. Transaction Publishers. 2001. {{ISBN|978-0-7658-0101-2}}. p. 11.</ref>


== See also == == See also ==
{{cols|colwidth=16em}}
{{Div col begin}}
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* '']'' – 1998 French book (''The Black Book of capitalism'') * '']''
* ] * ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ]
* ] * ]
* ] * ]
* ]
{{div col end}}
{{colend}}


== References == == References ==
; <big>Notes</big> ; Notes
{{Reflist|30em}} {{reflist}}


; <big>Bibliography</big> ; Bibliography
{{Refbegin}} {{refbegin|30em}}
* {{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=w_6PqBp64y0C&lpg=PP1&pg=PA2|title=Capitalism, Ethics and the Paradoxon of Self-Exploitation|last=Bacher|first=Christian|publisher=GRIN Verlag|year=2007|isbn=978-3-638-63658-2|location=Munich|page=2}} * {{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=w_6PqBp64y0C&pg=PA2|title=Capitalism, Ethics and the Paradoxon of Self-Exploitation|last=Bacher|first=Christian|publisher=GRIN Verlag|year=2007|isbn=978-3-638-63658-2|location=Munich|page=2|access-date=27 June 2015|archive-date=1 November 2015|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151101095357/https://books.google.com/books?id=w_6PqBp64y0C&lpg=PP1&pg=PA2|url-status=live}}
* {{cite book | last = Boldizzoni | first = Francesco | author-link = Francesco Boldizzoni | title = Foretelling the End of Capitalism: Intellectual Misadventures since Karl Marx | publisher= Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press| year = 2020 | isbn = 978-0-674-91932-7}}
* {{Cite journal|last= Carsel|first= Wilfred|year= 1940|title= The Slaveholders' Indictment of Northern Wage Slavery|journal= ]|volume= 6|issue= 4|pages= 504–20|jstor= 2192167|ref= harv}}
* {{cite journal|last= Carsel|first= Wilfred|year= 1940|title= The Slaveholders' Indictment of Northern Wage Slavery|journal= ]|volume= 6|issue= 4|pages= 504–520|jstor= 2192167|doi= 10.2307/2192167}}
* {{Cite book|title= The Law of the Labour Market: Industrialization, Employment, and Legal Evolution|last2= Wilkinson|first2= Frank|publisher= ]|year= 2005|isbn= 978-0-19-815281-1|location= Oxford|ref= harv|last1= Deakin|first1= Simon|author1-link= Simon Deakin|author2-link= Frank Wilkinson}}
* {{cite book|title=Business Ethics|last=De George|first=Richard T.|publisher=Macmillan|year=1986|isbn=978-0-02-328010-8|location=New York|page=104}} * {{cite book|title= The Law of the Labour Market: Industrialization, Employment, and Legal Evolution|last2= Wilkinson|first2= Frank|publisher=Oxford University Press|year= 2005|isbn= 978-0-19-815281-1|location= Oxford|last1= Deakin|first1= Simon|author1-link= Simon Deakin|author2-link= Frank Wilkinson}}
* {{Cite book|title= Britain's Gulag: The Brutal End of Empire in Kenya|last= Elkins|first= Caroline|publisher= ]|year= 2005|isbn= 978-0-224-07363-9|location= London|ref= harv|authorlink= Caroline Elkins}} * {{cite book|title=Business Ethics|url=https://archive.org/details/businessethics00dege|url-access=registration|last=De George|first=Richard T.|publisher=Macmillan|year=1986|isbn=978-0-02-328010-8|location=New York|page=}}
* {{Cite book|url= https://books.google.com/books?id=ECdb7EjiBnEC|title= Cannibals All! or, Slaves Without Masters|last= Fitzhugh|first= George|publisher= A. Morris|year= 1857|isbn= 9781429016438|location= Richmond,&nbsp;VA|ref= harv|authorlink= George Fitzhugh}} * {{cite book|title= Britain's Gulag: The Brutal End of Empire in Kenya|last= Elkins|first= Caroline|publisher= ]|year= 2005|isbn= 978-0-224-07363-9|location= London|author-link= Caroline Elkins}}
* {{cite book|url= https://books.google.com/books?id=ECdb7EjiBnEC|title= Cannibals All! or, Slaves Without Masters|last= Fitzhugh|first= George|publisher= A. Morris|year= 1857|isbn= 978-1-4290-1643-8|location= Richmond,&nbsp;VA|author-link= George Fitzhugh|access-date= 27 June 2015|archive-date= 18 October 2015|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20151018025643/https://books.google.com/books?id=ECdb7EjiBnEC|url-status= live}}
* {{cite book|title=Capitalism A Very Short Introduction|last=Fulcher|first=James|publisher=Oxford University Press|year=2004|isbn=978-0-19-280218-7|location=Oxford}}
* {{Cite book|title= ]|last= Graeber|first= David|publisher= Prickly Paradigm Press|year= 2004|isbn= 978-0-9728196-4-0|ref= harv}} * {{cite book|title=Capitalism A Very Short Introduction|last=Fulcher|first=James|publisher=Oxford University Press|year=2004|isbn=978-0-19-280218-7|location=Oxford|url=https://archive.org/details/capitalismverysh00fulc_0}}
* {{cite book|title= Possibilities: Essays on Hierarchy, Rebellion and Desire|last= Graeber|first= David|publisher= AK Press|year= 2007|isbn= 978-1-904859-66-6|ref= harv}} * {{cite book|title= Fragments of an Anarchist Anthropology|last= Graeber|first= David|publisher= Prickly Paradigm Press|year= 2004|isbn= 978-0-9728196-4-0|title-link= Fragments of an Anarchist Anthropology}}
* {{Cite journal|last2= Benoit|first2= Cecilia|year= 2007|title= From Wage Slaves to Wage Workers: Cultural Opportunity Structures and the Evolution of the Wage Demands of the Knights of Labor and the American Federation of Labor, 1880–1900|journal= ]|volume= 85|issue= 3|pages= 1393–411|doi=10.1353/sof.2007.0037|jstor= 4494978|ref= harv|last1= Hallgrimsdottir|first1= Helga Kristin}} * {{cite book|title= Possibilities: Essays on Hierarchy, Rebellion and Desire|last= Graeber|first= David|publisher= AK Press|year= 2007|isbn= 978-1-904859-66-6}}
* {{cite journal|last2= Benoit|first2= Cecilia|year= 2007|title= From Wage Slaves to Wage Workers: Cultural Opportunity Structures and the Evolution of the Wage Demands of the Knights of Labor and the American Federation of Labor, 1880–1900|journal= ]|volume= 85|issue= 3|pages= 1393–411|doi=10.1353/sof.2007.0037|jstor= 4494978|last1= Hallgrimsdottir|first1= Helga Kristin|s2cid= 154551793}}
* {{Cite book|url= http://www.academia.edu/4199690/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol._1_Global_Markets_and_Capitalism_editor_with_Barry_Gills_Sage_Publications_London_2007|title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism|last2= Gills|first2= Barry|publisher= Sage Publications|year= 2007|location= London|last1= James|first1= Paul|authorlink= Paul James (academic)}} * {{cite book|url= https://www.academia.edu/4199690|title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism|last2= Gills|first2= Barry|publisher= SAGE Publications|year= 2007|location= London|last1= James|first1= Paul|author-link= Paul James (academic)|access-date= 17 May 2014|archive-date= 23 September 2020|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063538/https://www.academia.edu/4199690/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol_1_Global_Markets_and_Capitalism_2007_|url-status= live}}
* Krahn, Harvey J., and Graham S. Lowe (1993). ''Work, Industry, and Canadian Society''. Second ed. Scarborough, Ont.: Nelson Canada. xii, 430 p. {{ISBN|0-17-603540-0}} * Krahn, Harvey J., and Graham S. Lowe (1993). ''Work, Industry, and Canadian Society''. 2nd ed. Scarborough, Ont.: Nelson Canada. xii, 430 p. {{ISBN|0-17-603540-0}}
* {{cite book|title= The Penguin Dictionary of Sociology|last2=Urry|first2= John|publisher= Penguin Books|year= 2000|isbn= 978-0-14-051380-6|edition= 4th|location= London|pages= 36–40|chapter=Capitalism|last1= Lash|first1=Scott|authorlink1=Scott Lash|authorlink2=John Urry (sociologist)|editor1-first= Nicholas|editor1-last=Abercrombie|editor2-first=Stephen|editor2-last=Hill|editor2-link=|editor3-first= Bryan S|editor3-last=Turner|editor3-link=Bryan S. Turner}} * {{cite book|title= The Penguin Dictionary of Sociology|last2=Urry|first2= John|publisher= Penguin Books|year= 2000|isbn= 978-0-14-051380-6|edition= 4th|location= London|pages= 36–40|chapter=Capitalism|last1= Lash|first1=Scott|author-link1=Scott Lash|author-link2=John Urry (sociologist)|editor1-first= Nicholas|editor1-last=Abercrombie|editor2-first=Stephen|editor2-last=Hill|editor3-first= Bryan S|editor3-last=Turner|editor3-link=Bryan S. Turner}}
* {{cite journal|date=August 2011|title= The Current Crisis and the Essence of Capitalism|url= http://www.themontrealreview.com/2009/The-current-crisis-and-the-essence-of-capitalism.php|journal= The Montreal Review|issn= 0707-9656|last1=McCraw|first1=Thomas K.|authorlink= Thomas K. McCraw}} * {{cite journal|date= August 2011|title= The Current Crisis and the Essence of Capitalism|url= http://www.themontrealreview.com/2009/The-current-crisis-and-the-essence-of-capitalism.php|journal= The Montreal Review|issn= 0707-9656|last1= McCraw|first1= Thomas K.|author-link= Thomas K. McCraw|access-date= 14 August 2011|archive-date= 8 September 2011|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20110908122337/http://www.themontrealreview.com/2009/The-current-crisis-and-the-essence-of-capitalism.php|url-status= live}}
* {{Cite journal|last= Nelson|first= John O.|year= 1995|title= That a Worker's Labour Cannot Be a Commodity|journal= ]|volume= 70|issue= 272|pages= 157–65|doi=10.1017/s0031819100065359|jstor= 3751199|ref= harv}} * {{cite journal|last= Nelson|first= John O.|year= 1995|title= That a Worker's Labour Cannot Be a Commodity|journal= ]|volume= 70|issue= 272|pages= 157–165|doi=10.1017/s0031819100065359|jstor= 3751199|s2cid= 171054136}}
* {{cite book|url=https://www.questia.com/read/4995070/profit-theory-and-capitalism|title=Profit Theory and Capitalism|publisher= University of Pennsylvania Press {{Subscription required|via=]}}|year=1983|isbn=978-0-8122-7863-7|location=Philadelphia|page=1|author=Obrinsky, Mark}} * {{cite book|url=https://archive.org/details/unset0000unse_o9p3/page/1|title=Profit Theory and Capitalism|publisher=University of Pennsylvania Press |year=1983|isbn=978-0-8122-7863-7|location=Philadelphia|page=|author=Obrinsky, Mark}}
* {{Cite book|title= The Kaiser's Holocaust: Germany's Forgotten Genocide|last2= Erichsen|first2= Casper W.|publisher= ]|year= 2010|isbn= 978-0-571-23141-6|location= London|ref= harv|last1= Olusoga|first1= David}} * {{cite book|title= The Kaiser's Holocaust: Germany's Forgotten Genocide|last2= Erichsen|first2= Casper W.|publisher= ]|year= 2010|isbn= 978-0-571-23141-6|location= London|last1= Olusoga|first1= David}}
* {{Cite book|url= http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/wage-labour/|title= Wage Labour and Capital|last= Marx|first= Karl|year= 1847|ref= harv|authorlink= Karl Marx}} * {{cite book|url= http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/wage-labour/|title= Wage Labour and Capital|last= Marx|first= Karl|year= 1847|author-link= Karl Marx|access-date= 25 March 2015|archive-date= 6 September 2019|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20190906075046/https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/wage-labour/|url-status= live}}
* {{Cite book|title= ]|last= Marx|first= Karl|publisher= ]|year= 1990|isbn= 978-0-14-044568-8|location= London|ref= harv|origyear= 1867}} * {{cite book|title= Capital, Volume I|last= Marx|first= Karl|publisher= Penguin Classics|year= 1990|isbn= 978-0-14-044568-8|location= London|orig-year= 1867|title-link= Capital, Volume I}}
* {{Cite book|title= The Wages of Whiteness: Race and the Making of the American Working Class|last= Roediger|first= David|publisher= ]|year= 2007a|isbn= 978-1-84467-145-8|edition= revised and expanded|location= London & New York|ref= harv|authorlink= David Roediger|origyear= 1991}} * {{cite book|title= The Wages of Whiteness: Race and the Making of the American Working Class|last= Roediger|first= David|publisher= ]|year= 2007a|isbn= 978-1-84467-145-8|edition= revised and expanded|location= London & New York|author-link= David Roediger|orig-year= 1991}}
* {{Cite journal|last= Roediger|first= David|year= 2007b|title= An Outmoded Approach to Labour and Slavery|journal= ]|volume= 60|pages= 245–50|jstor= 25149808|ref= harv|authorlink= David Roediger}} * {{cite journal|last= Roediger|first= David|year= 2007b|title= An Outmoded Approach to Labour and Slavery|journal= ]|volume= 60|pages= 245–250|jstor= 25149808|author-link= David Roediger}}
* {{Cite journal|last= Steinfeld|first= Robert|year= 2009|title= Coercion/Consent in Labor|url= http://www.compas.ox.ac.uk/fileadmin/files/Publications/working_papers/WP_2009/WP0966%20Steinfeld.pdf|series= COMPAS Working Paper No. 66|location= Oxford|publisher= ]|ref= harv|accessdate= 3 March 2013|deadurl= yes|archiveurl= https://web.archive.org/web/20140301173031/http://www.compas.ox.ac.uk/fileadmin/files/Publications/working_papers/WP_2009/WP0966%20Steinfeld.pdf|archivedate= 1 March 2014|df= dmy-all}} * {{cite journal|last= Steinfeld|first= Robert|year= 2009|title= Coercion/Consent in Labor|url= http://www.compas.ox.ac.uk/fileadmin/files/Publications/working_papers/WP_2009/WP0966%20Steinfeld.pdf|series= COMPAS Working Paper No. 66|location= Oxford|publisher= University of Oxford|access-date= 3 March 2013|url-status= dead|archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20140301173031/http://www.compas.ox.ac.uk/fileadmin/files/Publications/working_papers/WP_2009/WP0966%20Steinfeld.pdf|archive-date= 1 March 2014}}
* {{cite book|title=]|last=Wolf|first=Eric R.|publisher=University of California Press|year=1982|isbn=978-0-520-04459-3|location=Berkeley|authorlink=Eric Wolf}} * {{cite book|title=Europe and the People Without History|last=Wolf|first=Eric R.|publisher=University of California Press|year=1982|isbn=978-0-520-04459-3|location=Berkeley|author-link=Eric Wolf|title-link=Europe and the People Without History}}
* {{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=FZPyKjVguVoC|title=The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View|last=Wood|first=Ellen Meiksins|publisher=Verso|year=2002|isbn=978-1-85984-392-5|location=London|authorlink=Ellen Meiksins Wood}} * {{cite book|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=FZPyKjVguVoC|title=The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View|last=Wood|first=Ellen Meiksins|publisher=Verso|year=2002|isbn=978-1-85984-392-5|location=London|author-link=Ellen Meiksins Wood|access-date=27 June 2015|archive-date=28 November 2015|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151128060418/https://books.google.com/books?id=FZPyKjVguVoC|url-status=live}}
* {{Cite book|title= Peasant Revolution in Ethiopia: The Tigray People's Liberation Front, 1975–1991|last= Young|first= John|publisher= ]|year= 1997|isbn= 978-0-521-02606-2|location= Cambridge|ref= harv}} * {{cite book|title= Peasant Revolution in Ethiopia: The Tigray People's Liberation Front, 1975–1991|last= Young|first= John|publisher= Cambridge University Press|year= 1997|isbn= 978-0-521-02606-2|location= Cambridge}}
{{Refend}} {{refend}}


== Further reading == == Further reading ==
{{Refbegin|colwidth=30em}} {{refbegin|colwidth=30em}}
* ] (2011). ''America Beyond Capitalism: Reclaiming Our Wealth, Our Liberty, and Our Democracy, 2nd Edition.'' Democracy Collaborative Press. {{ISBN|0-9847857-0-1}}. * ] (2011). ''America Beyond Capitalism: Reclaiming Our Wealth, Our Liberty, and Our Democracy, 2nd Edition.'' Democracy Collaborative Press. {{ISBN|0-9847857-0-1}}.
* {{cite book|last1=Altvater |first1=Elmar |last2=Crist|first2=Eileen|last3=Haraway|first3=Donna|last4=Hartley|first4=Daniel|last5=Parenti|first5=Christian|last6=McBrien|first6=Justin|last7=Moore|first7=Jason|title=Anthropocene or Capitalocene? Nature, History, and the Crisis of Capitalism|date=2016|publisher=PM Press|location=|isbn=1629631485}} * {{cite book|last1=Altvater |first1=Elmar |last2=Crist|first2=Eileen|last3=Haraway|first3=Donna|author3-link=Donna Haraway|last4=Hartley|first4=Daniel|last5=Parenti|first5=Christian|last6=McBrien|first6=Justin|last7=Moore|first7=Jason|title=Anthropocene or Capitalocene? Nature, History, and the Crisis of Capitalism|date=2016|publisher=PM Press|isbn=978-1-62963-148-6}}
* Ascher, Ivan. ''Portfolio Society: On the Capitalist Mode of Prediction.'' Zone Books, 2016. {{ISBN|978-1935408741}} * Ascher, Ivan. ''Portfolio Society: On the Capitalist Mode of Prediction.'' Zone Books, 2016. {{ISBN|978-1935408741}}
* ] ''The Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of American Capitalism.'' ], ], 2014. {{ISBN|0-465-00296-X}}. * ] ''The Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of American Capitalism.'' New York, ], 2014. {{ISBN|0-465-00296-X}}.
* {{cite book | first = Richard | last = Barbrook | year = 2006 | title = The Class of the New | edition = paperback | publisher = OpenMute | location = London | isbn = 0-9550664-7-6 | url = http://www.theclassofthenew.net}} * {{cite book | first = Richard | last = Barbrook | year = 2006 | title = The Class of the New | edition = paperback | publisher = OpenMute | location = London | isbn = 978-0-9550664-7-4 | url = http://www.theclassofthenew.net | access-date = 11 June 2019 | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20180801045453/http://www.theclassofthenew.net/ | archive-date = 1 August 2018 | url-status = dead }}
* {{Cite book|last1= Block |first1= Fred |author1-link= Fred L. Block |last2= Somers |first2= Margaret R. |year= 2014|title= The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl Polyani's Critique|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= ]|isbn= 978-0-674-05071-6 |ref= harv }} * {{cite book|last1= Block |first1= Fred |author1-link= Fred L. Block |last2= Somers |first2= Margaret R. |year= 2014|title= The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl Polyani's Critique|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= Harvard University Press|isbn= 978-0-674-05071-6}}
* {{cite book | last = Boldizzoni | first = Francesco | author-link = Francesco Boldizzoni | title = Foretelling the End of Capitalism: Intellectual Misadventures since Karl Marx | publisher= Harvard University Press| year = 2020 | isbn = 978-0-674-91932-7}}
* Braudel, Fernand. ''Civilization and Capitalism''.
* ]. ''Civilization and Capitalism, 15th-18th Century'', 3 volumes.
* Callinicos, Alex. "Wage Labour and State Capitalism – A reply to Peter Binns and Mike Haynes", ''International Socialism'', second series, 12, Spring 1979.
* Callinicos, Alex. "Wage Labour and State Capitalism – A reply to Peter Binns and Mike Haynes", ''International Socialism'', 2nd series, 12, Spring 1979.
* {{cite book |last1=Case |first1=Anne |last2=Deaton |first2=Angus |author-link1=Anne Case |author-link2=Angus Deaton |date=2020 |title=Deaths of Despair and the Future of Capitalism |url=https://press.princeton.edu/books/hardcover/9780691190785/deaths-of-despair-and-the-future-of-capitalism |publisher=] |isbn=978-0-691-19078-5 |access-date=6 March 2020 |archive-date=7 March 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200307062358/https://press.princeton.edu/books/hardcover/9780691190785/deaths-of-despair-and-the-future-of-capitalism |url-status=live }}
* Farl, Erich. "The Genealogy of State Capitalism". In: ''International'' London, vol. 2, no. 1, 1973. * Farl, Erich. "The Genealogy of State Capitalism". In: ''International'' London, vol. 2, no. 1, 1973.
* {{cite book |last=Fisher|first=Mark |author-link=Mark Fisher|date=2009 |title=]|location= |publisher= ]|isbn=978-1-84694-317-1}}
* Gough, Ian. '''' New Left Review.
* Gough, Ian. '' {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120207145856/http://www.newleftreview.org/?view=558 |date=7 February 2012 }}'' New Left Review.
* ] '']'' (eng. translation by T. McCarthy). Boston, Beacon. ; .
* ] '']'' (eng. translation by T. McCarthy). Boston, Beacon. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151120102451/https://books.google.com/books?id=3WFy6vsyLNEC |date=20 November 2015 }}; .
* {{cite book | last = Harvey | first = David | authorlink = David Harvey | title = Seventeen Contradictions and the End of Capitalism | publisher= ] | year = 2014 | isbn = 0-19-936026-X}}
* {{cite book | last = Harvey | first = David | author-link = David Harvey | title = Seventeen Contradictions and the End of Capitalism | publisher= Oxford University Press| year = 2014 | isbn = 978-0-19-936026-0}}
* Hyman, Louis and Edward E. Baptist (2014). ''American Capitalism: A Reader.'' ]. {{ISBN|978-1-4767-8431-1}}.
* ] and ] (2014). ''American Capitalism: A Reader.'' Simon & Schuster. {{ISBN|978-1-4767-8431-1}}.
* {{Cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | authorlink= Paul James (academic) | last2= Patomäki | first2= Heikki | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 2: Global Finance and the New Global Economy | url= http://www.academia.edu/4211923/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol._2_Global_Finance_and_the_New_Global_Economy_editor_with_Heikki_Patomaki_Sage_Publications_London_2007 | publisher= Sage Publications | location= London}}
* {{cite book |last1=Ingham |first1=Geoffrey |title=Capitalism: With a New Postscript on the Financial Crisis and Its Aftermath |date=2008 |publisher=] |location=Cambridge |isbn=9780745636481}}
* {{Cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | authorlink= Paul James (academic) | last2= Palen | first2= Ronen | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 3: Global Economic Regimes and Institutions | url= http://www.academia.edu/4251331/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol._3_Global_Economic_Regimes_and_Institutions_editor_with_Ronen_Palan_Sage_Publications_London_2007 | publisher= Sage Publications | location= London}}
* {{cite book | year=2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | authorlink= Paul James (academic) | last2= O’Brien | first2= Robert | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 4: Globalizing Labour | url= http://www.academia.edu/4303461/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol._4_Globalizing_Labour_editor_with_Robert_OBrien_Sage_Publications_London_2007 | publisher= Sage Publications |location=London }} * {{cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | author-link= Paul James (academic) | last2= Patomäki | first2= Heikki | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 2: Global Finance and the New Global Economy | url= https://www.academia.edu/4211923 | publisher= SAGE Publications | location= London | access-date= 28 January 2018 | archive-date= 23 September 2020 | archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063542/https://www.academia.edu/4211923/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol_2_Global_Finance_and_the_New_Global_Economy_2007_ | url-status= live }}
* {{cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | author-link= Paul James (academic) | last2= Palen | first2= Ronen | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 3: Global Economic Regimes and Institutions | url= https://www.academia.edu/4251331 | publisher= Sage Publications | location= London | access-date= 28 January 2018 | archive-date= 23 September 2020 | archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063542/https://www.academia.edu/4251331/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol_3_Global_Economic_Regimes_and_Institutions_2007_ | url-status= live }}
* Jameson, Fredric (1991). '']''.
* {{cite book | year= 2007 | last1= James | first1= Paul | author-link= Paul James (academic) | last2= O'Brien | first2= Robert | title= Globalization and Economy, Vol. 4: Globalizing Labour | url= https://www.academia.edu/4303461 | publisher= Sage Publications | location= London | access-date= 28 January 2018 | archive-date= 23 September 2020 | archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063543/https://www.academia.edu/4303461/Globalization_and_Economy_Vol_4_Globalizing_Labour_2007_ | url-status= live }}
* Korstanje, Maximiliano E. (2016) The rise of Thana-Capitalism and Tourism. Abingdon, Routledge. {{ISBN|978-1138209268}}
* Jameson, Fredric (1991). '']''.
* {{cite book |last1=Kocka |first1=Jürgen |title=Capitalism: A Short History |date=2016 |publisher=] |location=Princeton |isbn=978-0691165226}}
* Kotler, Philip (2015). ''Confronting Capitalism: Real Solutions for a Troubled Economic System.'' AMACOM. {{ISBN|978-0814436455}} * Kotler, Philip (2015). ''Confronting Capitalism: Real Solutions for a Troubled Economic System.'' AMACOM. {{ISBN|978-0814436455}}
* Mandel, Ernest (1999). ''Late Capitalism.'' {{ISBN|978-1859842027}} * Mandel, Ernest (1999). ''Late Capitalism.'' {{ISBN|978-1859842027}}
* {{cite book | last = Mander | first = Jerry | authorlink = Jerry Mander | title = The Capitalism Papers: Fatal Flaws of an Obsolete System | publisher= Counterpoint | year = 2012 | isbn = 1-61902-158-7}} * {{cite book | last = Mander | first = Jerry | author-link = Jerry Mander | title = The Capitalism Papers: Fatal Flaws of an Obsolete System | publisher= Counterpoint | year = 2012 | isbn = 978-1-61902-158-7}}
* Marcel van der Linden, ''Western Marxism and the Soviet Union''. New York, Brill Publishers, 2007. * Marcel van der Linden, ''Western Marxism and the Soviet Union''. New York, Brill Publishers, 2007.
* Mayfield, Anthony. "Economics", in his ''On the Brink: Resource Depletion, Debt Collapse, and Super-technology'' (: On the Brink Publishing, 2013), pp.&nbsp;50–104. * Mayfield, Anthony. "Economics", in his ''On the Brink: Resource Depletion, Debt Collapse, and Super-technology'' (: On the Brink Publishing, 2013), pp.&nbsp;50–104.
* {{Cite book|last1= Musacchio |first1= Aldo |last2= Lazzarini |first2= Sergio G. |year= 2014|title= Reinventing State Capitalism: Leviathan in Business, Brazil and Beyond|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= ]|isbn= 978-0-674-72968-1 |ref= harv }} * {{cite book|last1= Musacchio |first1= Aldo |last2= Lazzarini |first2= Sergio G. |year= 2014|title= Reinventing State Capitalism: Leviathan in Business, Brazil and Beyond|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= Harvard University Press|isbn= 978-0-674-72968-1}}
* {{cite book|last=Newitz|first=Annalee |title=Pretend We′re Dead: Capitalist Monsters in American Pop Culture |date=2006|publisher=]|location=Durham, NC|isbn=978-0822337454|url=https://www.dukeupress.edu/Pretend-Were-Dead/}} * {{cite book|last=Newitz|first=Annalee|title=Pretend We're Dead: Capitalist Monsters in American Pop Culture|date=2006|publisher=Duke University Press|location=Durham, NC|isbn=978-0-8223-3745-4|url=https://www.dukeupress.edu/Pretend-Were-Dead/|access-date=26 October 2016|archive-date=26 October 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161026234517/https://www.dukeupress.edu/Pretend-Were-Dead/|url-status=live}}
* {{cite book |last1=Nitzan|first1=Jonathan |author-link1=Jonathan Nitzan|last2=Bichler|first2=Shimshon |author-link2=Shimshon Bichler|date=2009 |title=Capital as Power: A Study of Order and Creorder|url= |location= |publisher=]|page= |isbn=978-0-415-49680-3}}
* Panitch, Leo, and Sam Gindin (2012). ''The Making of Global Capitalism: the Political Economy of American Empire''. London, Verso. {{ISBN|978-1-84467-742-9}}. * Panitch, Leo, and Sam Gindin (2012). ''The Making of Global Capitalism: the Political Economy of American Empire''. London, Verso. {{ISBN|978-1-84467-742-9}}.
* {{Cite book|last= Piketty |first= Thomas |authorlink= Thomas Piketty |year= 2014|title= ]|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= ]|isbn= 0-674-43000-X |ref= harv }} * {{cite book|last= Piketty |first= Thomas |author-link= Thomas Piketty |year= 2014|title= Capital in the Twenty-First Century|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= ]|isbn= 978-0-674-43000-6 |title-link= Capital in the Twenty-First Century}}
* {{cite book|last= Piketty |first= Thomas |year= 2020|title=Capital and Ideology|location= Cambridge, MA |publisher= Belknap Press|isbn=978-0-674-98082-2|title-link= Capital and Ideology }}
* ] (2001). '']: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time.'' ]; 2nd ed. {{ISBN|0-8070-5643-X}} * ] (2001). '']: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time.'' ]; 2nd ed. {{ISBN|0-8070-5643-X}}
* {{cite book|title= Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life|last=Reisman|first= George|year= 1998|isbn= 978-0-915463-73-2
|publisher =Jameson Books}}
* ] (2009). ''Money, Greed, and God: Why Capitalism is the Solution and Not the Problem''. New York: ]. {{ISBN|978-0-06-137561-3}} * ] (2009). ''Money, Greed, and God: Why Capitalism is the Solution and Not the Problem''. New York: ]. {{ISBN|978-0-06-137561-3}}
* ] (2013). ''The Failure of Laissez-faire Capitalism: towards a New Economics for a Full World''. Atlanta, Ga.: Clarity Press. {{ISBN|978-0-9860362-5-5}} * ] (2013). ''The Failure of Laissez-faire Capitalism: towards a New Economics for a Full World''. Atlanta, Ga.: Clarity Press. {{ISBN|978-0-9860362-5-5}}
* ] ''Global Capitalism and the Crisis of Humanity.'' ], 2014. {{ISBN|1-107-69111-7}} * ] ''Global Capitalism and the Crisis of Humanity.'' Cambridge University Press, 2014. {{ISBN|1-107-69111-7}}
* {{Cite book|last=Schram | first=Sanford F. |authorlink=Sanford Schram|title=The Return of Ordinary Capitalism: Neoliberalism, Precarity, Occupy |year=2015|publisher=Oxford University Press|url=https://global.oup.com/academic/product/the-return-of-ordinary-capitalism-9780190253011?cc=us&lang=en& |isbn=978-0190253028 |ref=harv}} * {{cite book |last=Schram |first=Sanford F. |title=The Return of Ordinary Capitalism: Neoliberalism, Precarity, Occupy |year=2015 |publisher=Oxford University Press |url=https://global.oup.com/academic/product/the-return-of-ordinary-capitalism-9780190253011?cc=us& |isbn=978-0-19-025302-8 |access-date=12 February 2017 |archive-date=23 September 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200923063546/https://global.oup.com/academic/product/the-return-of-ordinary-capitalism-9780190253011?cc=us&lang=en& |url-status=live }}
* Shaikh, Anwar. (New Palgrave article) * Hoevet, Ocean. (New Palgrave article)
* ] (1916) ''Der moderne Kapitalismus. Historisch-systematische Darstellung des gesamteuropäischen Wirtschaftslebens von seinen Anfängen bis zur Gegenwart.'' Final edn. 1916, repr. 1969, paperback edn. (3 vols. in 6): 1987 Munich: dtv. (Also in Spanish; no English translation yet.)
* Skoll, G. R., & Korstanje, M. E. (2012). "Risks, totems, and fetishes in Marx and Freud". ''Sincronía'', (2), 11–27.
* {{cite book |last1=Sonenscher |first1=Michael |title=Capitalism: The Story behind the Word |date=2022 |publisher=] |location=Princeton |isbn=9780691237206}}
* ] (1916) ''Der moderne Kapitalismus. Historisch-systematische Darstellung des gesamteuropäischen Wirtschaftslebens von seinen Anfängen bis zur Gegenwart.'' Final edn. 1916, repr. 1969, paperback edn. (3 vols. in 6): 1987 Munich: dtv. (Also in Spanish; no English translation yet.)
* ], "Better, Faster, Stronger" (review of ], ''The Philosopher of Palo Alto: Mark Weisner, Xerox PARC, and the Original Internet of Things'', University of Chicago Press, 347 pp.; and ], ''Palo Alto: A History of California, Capitalism, and the World'', Little, Brown, 708 pp.), '']'', vol. LXX, no. 14 (21 September 2023), pp.&nbsp;38–40. " a place where the contradictions are sharpened to their finest points, above all the defining and enduring contradictions between ] and antidemocratic practice. There is nothing as American as celebrating ] while subverting it. Or as ]n." (p.&nbsp;40.)
* {{cite book | last = Wallerstein| first = Immanuel | authorlink = Immanuel Wallerstein | title = Historical Capitalism | publisher= ] | year = 1983 | isbn = 0-86091-761-4}}
* {{cite book | last = Wolff | first = Richard D. | authorlink = Richard D. Wolff | title = Democracy at Work: A Cure for Capitalism | publisher= ] | year = 2012 | isbn = 1-60846-247-1}} * {{cite book | last = Wallerstein| first = Immanuel | author-link = Immanuel Wallerstein | title = Historical Capitalism | publisher= ] | year = 1983 | isbn = 978-0-86091-761-8}}
* {{cite book | last = Wood | first = Ellen Meiksins | authorlink = Ellen Meiksins Wood | title = The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View | publisher= ] | year = 2002 | isbn = 1-85984-392-1}} * {{cite book | last = Wolff | first = Richard D. | author-link = Richard D. Wolff | title = Democracy at Work: A Cure for Capitalism | publisher= ] | year = 2012 | isbn = 978-1-60846-247-6}}
* {{cite book | last = Wood | first = Ellen Meiksins | author-link = Ellen Meiksins Wood | title = The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View | publisher= ] | year = 2002 | isbn = 978-1-85984-392-5}}
{{Refend}}
* {{cite book | last = Wolf | first = Martin | author-link = Martin Wolf | title = The Crisis of Democratic Capitalism | publisher = ] | year = 2023 | isbn = 9780241303429}}
{{refend}}


== External links == == External links ==
Line 673: Line 473:
{{Wiktionary}} {{Wiktionary}}
* {{In Our Time|Capitalism|p00545kv|Capitalism}} * {{In Our Time|Capitalism|p00545kv|Capitalism}}
* . ] * at '']'' Online.
* {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20180123134446/http://www.hup.harvard.edu/features/capitalism-and-its-discontents.html |date=23 January 2018 }}. ].
{{library resources box|by=no|onlinebooks=no|others=no|about=yes|label=Capitalism}}


{{Library resources box
|by=no
|onlinebooks=no
|others=no
|about=yes
|label=Capitalism}}
{{Aspects of capitalism}} {{Aspects of capitalism}}
{{navboxes
|list=
{{Political ideologies}}
{{Political philosophy}}
{{Marxist & Communist phraseology}} {{Marxist & Communist phraseology}}
{{Western culture}}
{{Portal bar|Companies|Capitalism|Politics}}
}}
{{Authority control}}
{{Portal bar|Companies|Capitalism|Law|Liberalism|Libertarianism|Politics}}
{{authority control}}

{{DEFAULTSORT:Capitalism}}
] ]
] ]
]
] ]
]
] ]
] ]
] ]
]

Latest revision as of 07:41, 11 January 2025

Economic system based on private ownership This article is about an economic system. For other uses, see Capitalism (disambiguation). "Capitalist" redirects here. For other uses, see Capitalist (disambiguation).

Part of a series on
Capitalism
Concepts
Economic systems
Economic theories
Origins
Development
Intellectuals
Related topics
Ideologies
Part of the behavioral sciences
Economics
Tools and methodologyEconomic theory

Empirical methods

Prescriptive and policy

Branches and subfields
Applications
Part of a series on
Economic systems
Major types
By ideology
By coordination
By regional model
Sectors
Property types
Transition
Coordination
Other types
Part of a series on
Liberalism
History
Principles
Philosophers
Politicians
Organizations
Regional variants
Related topics
Schools
Part of the politics series on
Neoliberalism
Ideas
Economics
Movements
Governance
Organizations
People
Related topics

Capitalism is an economic system based on the private ownership of the means of production and their operation for profit. The defining characteristics of capitalism include private property, capital accumulation, competitive markets, price systems, recognition of property rights, self-interest, economic freedom, work ethic, consumer sovereignty, decentralized decision-making, profit motive, a financial infrastructure of money and investment that makes possible credit and debt, entrepreneurship, commodification, voluntary exchange, wage labor, production of commodities and services, and a strong emphasis on innovation and economic growth. In a market economy, decision-making and investments are determined by owners of wealth, property, or ability to maneuver capital or production ability in capital and financial markets—whereas prices and the distribution of goods and services are mainly determined by competition in goods and services markets.

Economists, historians, political economists, and sociologists have adopted different perspectives in their analyses of capitalism and have recognized various forms of it in practice. These include laissez-faire or free-market capitalism, anarcho-capitalism, state capitalism, and welfare capitalism. Different forms of capitalism feature varying degrees of free markets, public ownership, obstacles to free competition, and state-sanctioned social policies. The degree of competition in markets and the role of intervention and regulation, as well as the scope of state ownership, vary across different models of capitalism. The extent to which different markets are free and the rules defining private property are matters of politics and policy. Most of the existing capitalist economies are mixed economies that combine elements of free markets with state intervention and in some cases economic planning.

Capitalism in its modern form emerged from agrarianism in England, as well as mercantilist practices by European countries between the 16th and 18th centuries. The Industrial Revolution of the 18th century established capitalism as a dominant mode of production, characterized by factory work, and a complex division of labor. Through the process of globalization, capitalism spread across the world in the 19th and 20th centuries, especially before World War I and after the end of the Cold War. During the 19th century, capitalism was largely unregulated by the state, but became more regulated in the post–World War II period through Keynesianism, followed by a return of more unregulated capitalism starting in the 1980s through neoliberalism.

The existence of market economies has been observed under many forms of government and across a vast array of historical periods, geographical locations, and cultural contexts. The modern industrial capitalist societies that exist today developed in Western Europe as a result of the Industrial Revolution. The accumulation of capital is the primary mechanism through which capitalist economies promote economic growth. However, it is a characteristic of such economies that they experience a business cycle of economic growth followed by recessions.

Etymology

The term "capitalist", meaning an owner of capital, appears earlier than the term "capitalism" and dates to the mid-17th century. "Capitalism" is derived from capital, which evolved from capitale, a late Latin word based on caput, meaning "head"—which is also the origin of "chattel" and "cattle" in the sense of movable property (only much later to refer only to livestock). Capitale emerged in the 12th to 13th centuries to refer to funds, stock of merchandise, sum of money or money carrying interest. By 1283, it was used in the sense of the capital assets of a trading firm and was often interchanged with other words—wealth, money, funds, goods, assets, property and so on.

The Hollantse (German: holländische) Mercurius uses "capitalists" in 1633 and 1654 to refer to owners of capital. In French, Étienne Clavier referred to capitalistes in 1788, four years before its first recorded English usage by Arthur Young in his work Travels in France (1792). In his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817), David Ricardo referred to "the capitalist" many times. English poet Samuel Taylor Coleridge used "capitalist" in his work Table Talk (1823). Pierre-Joseph Proudhon used the term in his first work, What is Property? (1840), to refer to the owners of capital. Benjamin Disraeli used the term in his 1845 work Sybil. Alexander Hamilton used "capitalist" in his Report of Manufactures presented to the United States Congress in 1791.

The initial use of the term "capitalism" in its modern sense is attributed to Louis Blanc in 1850 ("What I call 'capitalism' that is to say the appropriation of capital by some to the exclusion of others") and Pierre-Joseph Proudhon in 1861 ("Economic and social regime in which capital, the source of income, does not generally belong to those who make it work through their labor"). Karl Marx frequently referred to the "capital" and to the "capitalist mode of production" in Das Kapital (1867). Marx did not use the form capitalism but instead used capital, capitalist and capitalist mode of production, which appear frequently. Due to the word being coined by socialist critics of capitalism, economist and historian Robert Hessen stated that the term "capitalism" itself is a term of disparagement and a misnomer for economic individualism. Bernard Harcourt agrees with the statement that the term is a misnomer, adding that it misleadingly suggests that there is such a thing as "capital" that inherently functions in certain ways and is governed by stable economic laws of its own.

In the English language, the term "capitalism" first appears, according to the Oxford English Dictionary (OED), in 1854, in the novel The Newcomes by novelist William Makepeace Thackeray, where the word meant "having ownership of capital". Also according to the OED, Carl Adolph Douai, a German American socialist and abolitionist, used the term "private capitalism" in 1863.

Other terms sometimes used for capitalism are:

Definition

There is no universally agreed upon definition of capitalism; it is unclear whether or not capitalism characterizes an entire society, a specific type of social order, or crucial components or elements of a society. Societies officially founded in opposition to capitalism (such as the Soviet Union) have sometimes been argued to actually exhibit characteristics of capitalism. Nancy Fraser describes usage of the term "capitalism" by many authors as "mainly rhetorical, functioning less as an actual concept than as a gesture toward the need for a concept". Scholars who are uncritical of capitalism rarely actually use the term "capitalism". Some doubt that the term "capitalism" possesses valid scientific dignity, and it is generally not discussed in mainstream economics, with economist Daron Acemoglu suggesting that the term "capitalism" should be abandoned entirely. Consequently, understanding of the concept of capitalism tends to be heavily influenced by opponents of capitalism and by the followers and critics of Karl Marx.

History

Main article: History of capitalism
Cosimo de' Medici (pictured in a 16th-century portrait by Pontormo) built an international financial empire and was one of the first Medici bankers.
Augsburg, the centre of early capitalism

Capitalism, in its modern form, can be traced to the emergence of agrarian capitalism and mercantilism in the early Renaissance, in city-states like Florence. Capital has existed incipiently on a small scale for centuries in the form of merchant, renting and lending activities and occasionally as small-scale industry with some wage labor. Simple commodity exchange and consequently simple commodity production, which is the initial basis for the growth of capital from trade, have a very long history. During the Islamic Golden Age, Arabs promulgated capitalist economic policies such as free trade and banking. Their use of Indo-Arabic numerals facilitated bookkeeping. These innovations migrated to Europe through trade partners in cities such as Venice and Pisa. Italian mathematicians traveled the Mediterranean talking to Arab traders and returned to popularize the use of Indo-Arabic numerals in Europe.

Agrarianism

The economic foundations of the feudal agricultural system began to shift substantially in 16th-century England as the manorial system had broken down and land began to become concentrated in the hands of fewer landlords with increasingly large estates. Instead of a serf-based system of labor, workers were increasingly employed as part of a broader and expanding money-based economy. The system put pressure on both landlords and tenants to increase the productivity of agriculture to make profit; the weakened coercive power of the aristocracy to extract peasant surpluses encouraged them to try better methods, and the tenants also had incentive to improve their methods in order to flourish in a competitive labor market. Terms of rent for land were becoming subject to economic market forces rather than to the previous stagnant system of custom and feudal obligation.

Mercantilism

Main article: Mercantilism
A painting of a French seaport from 1638 at the height of mercantilism
Robert Clive with the Nawabs of Bengal after the Battle of Plassey which began the British rule in Bengal

The economic doctrine prevailing from the 16th to the 18th centuries is commonly called mercantilism. This period, the Age of Discovery, was associated with the geographic exploration of foreign lands by merchant traders, especially from England and the Low Countries. Mercantilism was a system of trade for profit, although commodities were still largely produced by non-capitalist methods. Most scholars consider the era of merchant capitalism and mercantilism as the origin of modern capitalism, although Karl Polanyi argued that the hallmark of capitalism is the establishment of generalized markets for what he called the "fictitious commodities", i.e. land, labor and money. Accordingly, he argued that "not until 1834 was a competitive labor market established in England, hence industrial capitalism as a social system cannot be said to have existed before that date".

England began a large-scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the Elizabethan Era (1558–1603). A systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through Thomas Mun's argument England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure. It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664.

European merchants, backed by state controls, subsidies and monopolies, made most of their profits by buying and selling goods. In the words of Francis Bacon, the purpose of mercantilism was "the opening and well-balancing of trade; the cherishing of manufacturers; the banishing of idleness; the repressing of waste and excess by sumptuary laws; the improvement and husbanding of the soil; the regulation of prices...".

After the period of the proto-industrialization, the British East India Company and the Dutch East India Company, after massive contributions from the Mughal Bengal, inaugurated an expansive era of commerce and trade. These companies were characterized by their colonial and expansionary powers given to them by nation-states. During this era, merchants, who had traded under the previous stage of mercantilism, invested capital in the East India Companies and other colonies, seeking a return on investment.

Industrial Revolution

Main article: Industrial Revolution
The Watt steam engine, fuelled primarily by coal, propelled the Industrial Revolution in Britain.

In the mid-18th century a group of economic theorists, led by David Hume (1711–1776) and Adam Smith (1723–1790), challenged fundamental mercantilist doctrines—such as the belief that the world's wealth remained constant and that a state could only increase its wealth at the expense of another state.

During the Industrial Revolution, industrialists replaced merchants as a dominant factor in the capitalist system and effected the decline of the traditional handicraft skills of artisans, guilds and journeymen. Industrial capitalism marked the development of the factory system of manufacturing, characterized by a complex division of labor between and within work process and the routine of work tasks; and eventually established the domination of the capitalist mode of production.

Industrial Britain eventually abandoned the protectionist policy formerly prescribed by mercantilism. In the 19th century, Richard Cobden (1804–1865) and John Bright (1811–1889), who based their beliefs on the Manchester School, initiated a movement to lower tariffs. In the 1840s Britain adopted a less protectionist policy, with the 1846 repeal of the Corn Laws and the 1849 repeal of the Navigation Acts. Britain reduced tariffs and quotas, in line with David Ricardo's advocacy of free trade.

Modernity

The gold standard formed the financial basis of the international economy from 1870 to 1914.

Broader processes of globalization carried capitalism across the world. By the beginning of the nineteenth century, a series of loosely connected market systems had come together as a relatively integrated global system, in turn intensifying processes of economic and other globalization. Late in the 20th century, capitalism overcame a challenge by centrally-planned economies and is now the encompassing system worldwide, with the mixed economy as its dominant form in the industrialized Western world.

Industrialization allowed cheap production of household items using economies of scale, while rapid population growth created sustained demand for commodities. The imperialism of the 18th-century decisively shaped globalization.

After the First and Second Opium Wars (1839–60) by Britain and France and the completion of the British conquest of India by 1858 and the French conquest of Africa, Polynesia and Indochina by 1887, vast populations of Asia became consumers of European exports. Europeans colonized areas of Africa and the Pacific islands. Colonisation by Europeans, notably of Africa by the British and French, yielded valuable natural resources such as rubber, diamonds and coal and helped fuel trade and investment between the European imperial powers, their colonies and the United States:

The inhabitant of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea, the various products of the whole earth, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep. Militarism and imperialism of racial and cultural rivalries were little more than the amusements of his daily newspaper. What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man was that age which came to an end in August 1914.

From the 1870s to the early 1920s, the global financial system was mainly tied to the gold standard. The United Kingdom first formally adopted this standard in 1821. Soon to follow were Canada in 1853, Newfoundland in 1865, the United States and Germany (de jure) in 1873. New technologies, such as the telegraph, the transatlantic cable, the radiotelephone, the steamship and railways allowed goods and information to move around the world to an unprecedented degree.

In the United States, the term "capitalist" primarily referred to powerful businessmen until the 1920s due to widespread societal skepticism and criticism of capitalism and its most ardent supporters.

The New York stock exchange traders' floor (1963)

Contemporary capitalist societies developed in the West from 1950 to the present and this type of system continues throughout the world—relevant examples started in the United States after the 1950s, France after the 1960s, Spain after the 1970s, Poland after 2015, and others. At this stage most capitalist markets are considered developed and characterized by developed private and public markets for equity and debt, a high standard of living (as characterized by the World Bank and the IMF), large institutional investors and a well-funded banking system. A significant managerial class has emerged and decides on a significant proportion of investments and other decisions. A different future than that envisioned by Marx has started to emerge—explored and described by Anthony Crosland in the United Kingdom in his 1956 book The Future of Socialism and by John Kenneth Galbraith in North America in his 1958 book The Affluent Society, 90 years after Marx's research on the state of capitalism in 1867.

The postwar boom ended in the late 1960s and early 1970s and the economic situation grew worse with the rise of stagflation. Monetarism, a modification of Keynesianism that is more compatible with laissez-faire analyses, gained increasing prominence in the capitalist world, especially under the years in office of Ronald Reagan in the United States (1981–1989) and of Margaret Thatcher in the United Kingdom (1979–1990). Public and political interest began shifting away from the so-called collectivist concerns of Keynes's managed capitalism to a focus on individual choice, called "remarketized capitalism".

The end of the Cold War and the dissolution of the Soviet Union allowed for capitalism to become a truly global system in a way not seen since before World War I. The development of the neoliberal global economy would have been impossible without the fall of communism.

Harvard Kennedy School economist Dani Rodrik distinguishes between three historical variants of capitalism:

  • Capitalism 1.0 during the 19th century entailed largely unregulated markets with a minimal role for the state (aside from national defense, and protecting property rights);
  • Capitalism 2.0 during the post-World War II years entailed Keynesianism, a substantial role for the state in regulating markets, and strong welfare states;
  • Capitalism 2.1 entailed a combination of unregulated markets, globalization, and various national obligations by states.

Relationship to democracy

The relationship between democracy and capitalism is a contentious area in theory and in popular political movements. The extension of adult-male suffrage in 19th-century Britain occurred along with the development of industrial capitalism and representative democracy became widespread at the same time as capitalism, leading capitalists to posit a causal or mutual relationship between them. However, according to some authors in the 20th-century, capitalism also accompanied a variety of political formations quite distinct from liberal democracies, including fascist regimes, absolute monarchies and single-party states. Democratic peace theory asserts that democracies seldom fight other democracies, but others suggest this may be because of political similarity or stability, rather than because they are "democratic" or "capitalist". Critics argue that though economic growth under capitalism has led to democracy, it may not do so in the future as authoritarian régimes have been able to manage economic growth using some of capitalism's competitive principles without making concessions to greater political freedom.

Political scientists Torben Iversen and David Soskice see democracy and capitalism as mutually supportive. Robert Dahl argued in On Democracy that capitalism was beneficial for democracy because economic growth and a large middle class were good for democracy. He also argued that a market economy provided a substitute for government control of the economy, which reduces the risks of tyranny and authoritarianism.

In his book The Road to Serfdom (1944), Friedrich Hayek (1899–1992) asserted that the free-market understanding of economic freedom as present in capitalism is a requisite of political freedom. He argued that the market mechanism is the only way of deciding what to produce and how to distribute the items without using coercion. Milton Friedman and Ronald Reagan also promoted this view. Friedman claimed that centralized economic operations are always accompanied by political repression. In his view, transactions in a market economy are voluntary and the wide diversity that voluntary activity permits is a fundamental threat to repressive political leaders and greatly diminishes their power to coerce. Some of Friedman's views were shared by John Maynard Keynes, who believed that capitalism was vital for freedom to survive and thrive. Freedom House, an American think-tank that conducts international research on, and advocates for, democracy, political freedom and human rights, has argued that "there is a high and statistically significant correlation between the level of political freedom as measured by Freedom House and economic freedom as measured by the Wall Street Journal/Heritage Foundation survey".

In Capital in the Twenty-First Century (2013), Thomas Piketty of the Paris School of Economics asserted that inequality is the inevitable consequence of economic growth in a capitalist economy and the resulting concentration of wealth can destabilize democratic societies and undermine the ideals of social justice upon which they are built.

States with capitalistic economic systems have thrived under political regimes deemed to be authoritarian or oppressive. Singapore has a successful open market economy as a result of its competitive, business-friendly climate and robust rule of law. Nonetheless, it often comes under fire for its style of government which, though democratic and consistently one of the least corrupt, operates largely under a one-party rule. Furthermore, it does not vigorously defend freedom of expression as evidenced by its government-regulated press, and its penchant for upholding laws protecting ethnic and religious harmony, judicial dignity and personal reputation. The private (capitalist) sector in the People's Republic of China has grown exponentially and thrived since its inception, despite having an authoritarian government. Augusto Pinochet's rule in Chile led to economic growth and high levels of inequality by using authoritarian means to create a safe environment for investment and capitalism. Similarly, Suharto's authoritarian reign and extirpation of the Communist Party of Indonesia allowed for the expansion of capitalism in Indonesia.

The term "capitalism" in its modern sense is often attributed to Karl Marx. In his Das Kapital, Marx analyzed the "capitalist mode of production" using a method of understanding today known as Marxism. However, Marx himself rarely used the term "capitalism" while it was used twice in the more political interpretations of his work, primarily authored by his collaborator Friedrich Engels. In the 20th century, defenders of the capitalist system often replaced the term "capitalism" with phrases such as free enterprise and private enterprise and replaced "capitalist" with rentier and investor in reaction to the negative connotations associated with capitalism.

Characteristics

Further information: Academic perspectives on capitalism

In general, capitalism as an economic system and mode of production can be summarized by the following:

  • Capital accumulation: production for profit and accumulation as the implicit purpose of all or most of production, constriction or elimination of production formerly carried out on a common social or private household basis.
  • Commodity production: production for exchange on a market; to maximize exchange-value instead of use-value.
  • Exchange of goods or services, can be enabled by contracts. Exchange of services can be in form of wage labor.
  • Private ownership of the means of production:
  • The investment of money to make a profit.
  • The use of the price mechanism to allocate resources between competing uses.
  • Economically efficient use of the factors of production and raw materials due to maximization of value added in the production process.
  • Freedom of capitalists to act in their self-interest in managing their business and investments.
  • Capital suppliance by "the single owner of a firm, or by shareholders in the case of a joint-stock company."

Market

In free market and laissez-faire forms of capitalism, markets are used most extensively with minimal or no regulation over the pricing mechanism. In mixed economies, which are almost universal today, markets continue to play a dominant role, but they are regulated to some extent by the state in order to correct market failures, promote social welfare, conserve natural resources, fund defense and public safety or other rationale. In state capitalist systems, markets are relied upon the least, with the state relying heavily on state-owned enterprises or indirect economic planning to accumulate capital.

Competition arises when more than one producer is trying to sell the same or similar products to the same buyers. Adherents of the capitalist theory believe that competition leads to innovation and more affordable prices. Monopolies or cartels can develop, especially if there is no competition. A monopoly occurs when a firm has exclusivity over a market. Hence, the firm can engage in rent seeking behaviors such as limiting output and raising prices because it has no fear of competition.

Governments have implemented legislation for the purpose of preventing the creation of monopolies and cartels. In 1890, the Sherman Antitrust Act became the first legislation passed by the United States Congress to limit monopolies.

Wage labor

Main article: Wage labor

Wage labor, usually referred to as paid work, paid employment, or paid labor, refers to the socioeconomic relationship between a worker and an employer in which the worker sells their labor power under a formal or informal employment contract. These transactions usually occur in a labor market where wages or salaries are market-determined.

In exchange for the money paid as wages (usual for short-term work-contracts) or salaries (in permanent employment contracts), the work product generally becomes the undifferentiated property of the employer. A wage laborer is a person whose primary means of income is from the selling of their labor in this way.

Profit motive

Main article: Profit motive

The profit motive, in the theory of capitalism, is the desire to earn income in the form of profit. Stated differently, the reason for a business's existence is to turn a profit. The profit motive functions according to rational choice theory, or the theory that individuals tend to pursue what is in their own best interests. Accordingly, businesses seek to benefit themselves and/or their shareholders by maximizing profit.

In capitalist theoretics, the profit motive is said to ensure that resources are being allocated efficiently. For instance, Austrian economist Henry Hazlitt explains: "If there is no profit in making an article, it is a sign that the labor and capital devoted to its production are misdirected: the value of the resources that must be used up in making the article is greater than the value of the article itself".

Socialist theorists note that, unlike mercantilists, capitalists accumulate their profits while expecting their profit rates to remain the same. This causes problems as earnings in the rest of society do not increase in the same proportion.

Private property

Main article: Private property

The relationship between the state, its formal mechanisms, and capitalist societies has been debated in many fields of social and political theory, with active discussion since the 19th century. Hernando de Soto is a contemporary Peruvian economist who has argued that an important characteristic of capitalism is the functioning state protection of property rights in a formal property system where ownership and transactions are clearly recorded.

According to de Soto, this is the process by which physical assets are transformed into capital, which in turn may be used in many more ways and much more efficiently in the market economy. A number of Marxian economists have argued that the inclosure acts in England and similar legislation elsewhere were an integral part of capitalist primitive accumulation and that specific legal frameworks of private land ownership have been integral to the development of capitalism.

Private property rights are not absolute, as in many countries the state has the power to seize private property, typically for public use, under the powers of eminent domain.

Market competition

Main article: Competition (economics)

In capitalist economics, market competition is the rivalry among sellers trying to achieve such goals as increasing profits, market share and sales volume by varying the elements of the marketing mix: price, product, distribution and promotion. Merriam-Webster defines competition in business as "the effort of two or more parties acting independently to secure the business of a third party by offering the most favourable terms". It was described by Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations (1776) and later economists as allocating productive resources to their most highly valued uses and encouraging efficiency. Smith and other classical economists before Antoine Augustine Cournot were referring to price and non-price rivalry among producers to sell their goods on best terms by bidding of buyers, not necessarily to a large number of sellers nor to a market in final equilibrium. Competition is widespread throughout the market process. It is a condition where "buyers tend to compete with other buyers, and sellers tend to compete with other sellers". In offering goods for exchange, buyers competitively bid to purchase specific quantities of specific goods which are available, or might be available if sellers were to choose to offer such goods. Similarly, sellers bid against other sellers in offering goods on the market, competing for the attention and exchange resources of buyers. Competition results from scarcity, as it is not possible to satisfy all conceivable human wants, and occurs as people try to meet the criteria being used to determine allocation.

In the works of Adam Smith, the idea of capitalism is made possible through competition which creates growth. Although capitalism had not entered mainstream economics at the time of Smith, it is vital to the construction of his ideal society. One of the foundational blocks of capitalism is competition. Smith believed that a prosperous society is one where "everyone should be free to enter and leave the market and change trades as often as he pleases." He believed that the freedom to act in one's self-interest is essential for the success of a capitalist society. In response to the idea that if all participants focus on their own goals, society's well-being will be water under the bridge, Smith maintains that despite the concerns of intellectuals, "global trends will hardly be altered if they refrain from pursuing their personal ends." He insisted that the actions of a few participants cannot alter the course of society. Instead, Smith maintained that they should focus on personal progress instead and that this will result in overall growth to the whole.

Competition between participants, "who are all endeavoring to justle one another out of employment, obliges every man to endeavor to execute his work" through competition towards growth.

Economic growth

Further information: Economic growth
This section needs expansion. You can help by adding to it. (January 2021)

Economic growth is a characteristic tendency of capitalist economies. However, capitalist economies may experience fluctuations in growth that cannot be accounted for by demographic or technological changes. These fluctuations, which involve sustained periods of economic growth and recession, are referred to as business cycles in macroeconomics. Economic growth is measured as growth in investment, economic output, and economic consumption per capita. Changes in hours of employment on their own are not considered as a factor of economic growth.

As a mode of production

Further information: Mode of production

The capitalist mode of production refers to the systems of organising production and distribution within capitalist societies. Private money-making in various forms (renting, banking, merchant trade, production for profit and so on) preceded the development of the capitalist mode of production as such.

The term capitalist mode of production is defined by private ownership of the means of production, extraction of surplus value by the owning class for the purpose of capital accumulation, wage-based labor and, at least as far as commodities are concerned, being market-based.

Capitalism in the form of money-making activity has existed in the shape of merchants and money-lenders who acted as intermediaries between consumers and producers engaging in simple commodity production (hence the reference to "merchant capitalism") since the beginnings of civilisation. What is specific about the "capitalist mode of production" is that most of the inputs and outputs of production are supplied through the market (i.e. they are commodities) and essentially all production is in this mode. By contrast, in flourishing feudalism most or all of the factors of production, including labor, are owned by the feudal ruling class outright and the products may also be consumed without a market of any kind, it is production for use within the feudal social unit and for limited trade. This has the important consequence that, under capitalism, the whole organisation of the production process is reshaped and re-organised to conform with economic rationality as bounded by capitalism, which is expressed in price relationships between inputs and outputs (wages, non-labor factor costs, sales and profits) rather than the larger rational context faced by society overall—that is, the whole process is organised and re-shaped in order to conform to "commercial logic". Essentially, capital accumulation comes to define economic rationality in capitalist production.

A society, region or nation is capitalist if the predominant source of incomes and products being distributed is capitalist activity, but even so this does not yet mean necessarily that the capitalist mode of production is dominant in that society.

Mixed economies rely on the nation they are in to provide some goods or services, while the free market produces and maintains the rest.

Role of government

Government agencies regulate the standards of service in many industries, such as airlines and broadcasting, as well as financing a wide range of programs. In addition, the government regulates the flow of capital and uses financial tools such as the interest rate to control such factors as inflation and unemployment.

Supply and demand

Main article: Supply and demand
The economic model of supply and demand states that the price P of a product is determined by a balance between production at each price (supply S) and the desires of those with purchasing power at each price (demand D): the diagram shows a positive shift in demand from D1 to D2, resulting in an increase in price (P) and quantity sold (Q) of the product.

In capitalist economic structures, supply and demand is an economic model of price determination in a market. It postulates that in a perfectly competitive market, the unit price for a particular good will vary until it settles at a point where the quantity demanded by consumers (at the current price) will equal the quantity supplied by producers (at the current price), resulting in an economic equilibrium for price and quantity.

The "basic laws" of supply and demand, as described by David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam, are the following four:

  1. If demand increases (demand curve shifts to the right) and supply remains unchanged, then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price.
  2. If demand decreases (demand curve shifts to the left) and supply remains unchanged, then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price.
  3. If demand remains unchanged and supply increases (supply curve shifts to the right), then a surplus occurs, leading to a lower equilibrium price.
  4. If demand remains unchanged and supply decreases (supply curve shifts to the left), then a shortage occurs, leading to a higher equilibrium price.

Supply schedule

A supply schedule is a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied.

Demand schedule

A demand schedule, depicted graphically as the demand curve, represents the amount of some goods that buyers are willing and able to purchase at various prices, assuming all determinants of demand other than the price of the good in question, such as income, tastes and preferences, the price of substitute goods and the price of complementary goods, remain the same. According to the law of demand, the demand curve is almost always represented as downward sloping, meaning that as price decreases, consumers will buy more of the good.

Just like the supply curves reflect marginal cost curves, demand curves are determined by marginal utility curves.

Equilibrium

Further information: Economic equilibrium

In the context of supply and demand, economic equilibrium refers to a state where economic forces such as supply and demand are balanced and in the absence of external influences the (equilibrium) values of economic variables will not change. For example, in the standard text-book model of perfect competition equilibrium occurs at the point at which quantity demanded and quantity supplied are equal. Market equilibrium, in this case, refers to a condition where a market price is established through competition such that the amount of goods or services sought by buyers is equal to the amount of goods or services produced by sellers. This price is often called the competitive price or market clearing price and will tend not to change unless demand or supply changes.

Partial equilibrium

Main article: Partial equilibrium

Partial equilibrium, as the name suggests, takes into consideration only a part of the market to attain equilibrium. Jain proposes (attributed to George Stigler): "A partial equilibrium is one which is based on only a restricted range of data, a standard example is price of a single product, the prices of all other products being held fixed during the analysis".

History

According to Hamid S. Hosseini, the "power of supply and demand" was discussed to some extent by several early Muslim scholars, such as fourteenth century Mamluk scholar Ibn Taymiyyah, who wrote: "If desire for goods increases while its availability decreases, its price rises. On the other hand, if availability of the good increases and the desire for it decreases, the price comes down".

Adam Smith

John Locke's 1691 work Some Considerations on the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money includes an early and clear description of supply and demand and their relationship. In this description, demand is rent: "The price of any commodity rises or falls by the proportion of the number of buyer and sellers" and "that which regulates the price... is nothing else but their quantity in proportion to their rent".

David Ricardo titled one chapter of his 1817 work Principles of Political Economy and Taxation "On the Influence of Demand and Supply on Price". In Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Ricardo more rigorously laid down the idea of the assumptions that were used to build his ideas of supply and demand.

In his 1870 essay "On the Graphical Representation of Supply and Demand", Fleeming Jenkin in the course of "introduc the diagrammatic method into the English economic literature" published the first drawing of supply and demand curves therein, including comparative statics from a shift of supply or demand and application to the labor market. The model was further developed and popularized by Alfred Marshall in the 1890 textbook Principles of Economics.

Types

There are many variants of capitalism in existence that differ according to country and region. They vary in their institutional makeup and by their economic policies. The common features among all the different forms of capitalism are that they are predominantly based on the private ownership of the means of production and the production of goods and services for profit; the market-based allocation of resources; and the accumulation of capital.

They include advanced capitalism, corporate capitalism, finance capitalism, free-market capitalism, mercantilism, state capitalism and welfare capitalism. Other theoretical variants of capitalism include anarcho-capitalism, community capitalism, humanistic capitalism, neo-capitalism, state monopoly capitalism, and technocapitalism.

Advanced

Main article: Advanced capitalism

Advanced capitalism is the situation that pertains to a society in which the capitalist model has been integrated and developed deeply and extensively for a prolonged period. Various writers identify Antonio Gramsci as an influential early theorist of advanced capitalism, even if he did not use the term himself. In his writings, Gramsci sought to explain how capitalism had adapted to avoid the revolutionary overthrow that had seemed inevitable in the 19th century. At the heart of his explanation was the decline of raw coercion as a tool of class power, replaced by use of civil society institutions to manipulate public ideology in the capitalists' favour.

Jürgen Habermas has been a major contributor to the analysis of advanced-capitalistic societies. Habermas observed four general features that characterise advanced capitalism:

  1. Concentration of industrial activity in a few large firms.
  2. Constant reliance on the state to stabilise the economic system.
  3. A formally democratic government that legitimises the activities of the state and dissipates opposition to the system.
  4. The use of nominal wage increases to pacify the most restless segments of the work force.

Corporate

Main article: Corporate capitalism See also: Crony capitalism and State monopoly capitalism

Corporate capitalism is a free or mixed-market capitalist economy characterized by the dominance of hierarchical and bureaucratic corporations.

Finance

Main article: Finance capitalism See also: Capitalist mode of production (Marxist theory)

Finance capitalism is the subordination of processes of production to the accumulation of money profits in a financial system. In their critique of capitalism, Marxism and Leninism both emphasise the role of finance capital as the determining and ruling-class interest in capitalist society, particularly in the latter stages.

Rudolf Hilferding is credited with first bringing the term finance capitalism into prominence through Finance Capital, his 1910 study of the links between German trusts, banks and monopolies—a study subsumed by Vladimir Lenin into Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism (1917), his analysis of the imperialist relations of the great world powers. Lenin concluded that the banks at that time operated as "the chief nerve centres of the whole capitalist system of national economy". For the Comintern (founded in 1919), the phrase "dictatorship of finance capitalism" became a regular one.

Fernand Braudel would later point to two earlier periods when finance capitalism had emerged in human history—with the Genoese in the 16th century and with the Dutch in the 17th and 18th centuries—although at those points it developed from commercial capitalism. Giovanni Arrighi extended Braudel's analysis to suggest that a predominance of finance capitalism is a recurring, long-term phenomenon, whenever a previous phase of commercial/industrial capitalist expansion reaches a plateau.

Free market

Main article: Free-market capitalism See also: Laissez-faire

A capitalist free-market economy is an economic system where prices for goods and services are set entirely by the forces of supply and demand and are expected, by its adherents, to reach their point of equilibrium without intervention by government policy. It typically entails support for highly competitive markets and private ownership of the means of production. Laissez-faire capitalism is a more extensive form of this free-market economy, but one in which the role of the state is limited to protecting property rights. In anarcho-capitalist theory, property rights are protected by private firms and market-generated law. According to anarcho-capitalists, this entails property rights without statutory law through market-generated tort, contract and property law, and self-sustaining private industry.

Fernand Braudel argued that free market exchange and capitalism are to some degree opposed; free market exchange involves transparent public transactions and a large number of equal competitors, while capitalism involves a small number of participants using their capital to control the market via private transactions, control of information, and limitation of competition.

Mercantile

Main article: Mercantilism See also: Protectionism
The subscription room at Lloyd's of London in the early 19th century

Mercantilism is a nationalist form of early capitalism that came into existence approximately in the late 16th century. It is characterized by the intertwining of national business interests with state-interest and imperialism. Consequently, the state apparatus is used to advance national business interests abroad. An example of this is colonists living in America who were only allowed to trade with and purchase goods from their respective mother countries (e.g., United Kingdom, France and Portugal). Mercantilism was driven by the belief that the wealth of a nation is increased through a positive balance of trade with other nations—it corresponds to the phase of capitalist development sometimes called the primitive accumulation of capital.

Social

Main article: Social market economy See also: Nordic model

A social market economy is a free-market or mixed-market capitalist system, sometimes classified as a coordinated market economy, where government intervention in price formation is kept to a minimum, but the state provides significant services in areas such as social security, health care, unemployment benefits and the recognition of labor rights through national collective bargaining arrangements.

This model is prominent in Western and Northern European countries as well as Japan, albeit in slightly different configurations. The vast majority of enterprises are privately owned in this economic model. Rhine capitalism is the contemporary model of capitalism and adaptation of the social market model that exists in continental Western Europe today.

State

Main article: State capitalism

State capitalism is a capitalist market economy dominated by state-owned enterprises, where the state enterprises are organized as commercial, profit-seeking businesses. The designation has been used broadly throughout the 20th century to designate a number of different economic forms, ranging from state-ownership in market economies to the command economies of the former Eastern Bloc. According to Aldo Musacchio, a professor at Harvard Business School, state capitalism is a system in which governments, whether democratic or autocratic, exercise a widespread influence on the economy either through direct ownership or various subsidies. Musacchio notes a number of differences between today's state capitalism and its predecessors. In his opinion, gone are the days when governments appointed bureaucrats to run companies: the world's largest state-owned enterprises are now traded on the public markets and kept in good health by large institutional investors. Contemporary state capitalism is associated with the East Asian model of capitalism, dirigisme and the economy of Norway. Alternatively, Merriam-Webster defines state capitalism as "an economic system in which private capitalism is modified by a varying degree of government ownership and control".

In Socialism: Utopian and Scientific, Friedrich Engels argued that state-owned enterprises would characterize the final stage of capitalism, consisting of ownership and management of large-scale production and communication by the bourgeois state. In his writings, Vladimir Lenin characterized the economy of Soviet Russia as state capitalist, believing state capitalism to be an early step toward the development of socialism.

Some economists and left-wing academics including Richard D. Wolff and Noam Chomsky, as well as many Marxist philosophers and revolutionaries such as Raya Dunayevskaya and C.L.R. James, argue that the economies of the former Soviet Union and Eastern Bloc represented a form of state capitalism because their internal organization within enterprises and the system of wage labor remained intact.

The term is not used by Austrian School economists to describe state ownership of the means of production. The economist Ludwig von Mises argued that the designation of state capitalism was a new label for the old labels of state socialism and planned economy and differed only in non-essentials from these earlier designations.

Welfare

Main article: Welfare capitalism See also: Economic interventionism and Mixed economy

Welfare capitalism is capitalism that includes social welfare policies. Today, welfare capitalism is most often associated with the models of capitalism found in Central and Northern Europe such as the Nordic model, social market economy and Rhine capitalism. In some cases, welfare capitalism exists within a mixed economy, but welfare states can and do exist independently of policies common to mixed economies such as state interventionism and extensive regulation.

A mixed economy is a largely market-based capitalist economy consisting of both private and public ownership of the means of production and economic interventionism through macroeconomic policies intended to correct market failures, reduce unemployment and keep inflation low. The degree of intervention in markets varies among different countries. Some mixed economies such as France under dirigisme also featured a degree of indirect economic planning over a largely capitalist-based economy.

Most modern capitalist economies are defined as mixed economies to some degree, however French economist Thomas Piketty state that capitalist economies might shift to a much more laissez-faire approach in the near future.

Eco-capitalism

Eco-capitalism, also known as "environmental capitalism" or (sometimes) "green capitalism", is the view that capital exists in nature as "natural capital" (ecosystems that have ecological yield) on which all wealth depends. Therefore, governments should use market-based policy-instruments (such as a carbon tax) to resolve environmental problems.

The term "Blue Greens" is often applied to those who espouse eco-capitalism. Eco-capitalism can be thought of as the right-wing equivalent to Red Greens.

Sustainable capitalism

Sustainable capitalism is a conceptual form of capitalism based upon sustainable practices that seek to preserve humanity and the planet, while reducing externalities and bearing a resemblance of capitalist economic policy. A capitalistic economy must expand to survive and find new markets to support this expansion. Capitalist systems are often destructive to the environment as well as certain individuals without access to proper representation. However, sustainability provides quite the opposite; it implies not only a continuation, but a replenishing of resources. Sustainability is often thought of to be related to environmentalism, and sustainable capitalism applies sustainable principles to economic governance and social aspects of capitalism as well.

The importance of sustainable capitalism has been more recently recognized, but the concept is not new. Changes to the current economic model would have heavy social environmental and economic implications and require the efforts of individuals, as well as compliance of local, state and federal governments. Controversy surrounds the concept as it requires an increase in sustainable practices and a marked decrease in current consumptive behaviors.

This is a concept of capitalism described in Al Gore and David Blood's manifesto for the Generation Investment Management to describe a long-term political, economic and social structure which would mitigate current threats to the planet and society. According to their manifesto, sustainable capitalism would integrate the environmental, social and governance (ESG) aspects into risk assessment in attempt to limit externalities. Most of the ideas they list are related to economic changes, and social aspects, but strikingly few are explicitly related to any environmental policy change.

Capital accumulation

Main article: Capital accumulation

The accumulation of capital is the process of "making money" or growing an initial sum of money through investment in production. Capitalism is based on the accumulation of capital, whereby financial capital is invested in order to make a profit and then reinvested into further production in a continuous process of accumulation. In Marxian economic theory, this dynamic is called the law of value. Capital accumulation forms the basis of capitalism, where economic activity is structured around the accumulation of capital, defined as investment in order to realize a financial profit. In this context, "capital" is defined as money or a financial asset invested for the purpose of making more money (whether in the form of profit, rent, interest, royalties, capital gain or some other kind of return).

In mainstream economics, accounting and Marxian economics, capital accumulation is often equated with investment of profit income or savings, especially in real capital goods. The concentration and centralisation of capital are two of the results of such accumulation. In modern macroeconomics and econometrics, the phrase "capital formation" is often used in preference to "accumulation", though the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) refers nowadays to "accumulation". The term "accumulation" is occasionally used in national accounts.

Wage labor

Main article: Wage labour
An industrial worker among heavy steel machine parts (Kinex Bearings, Bytča, Slovakia, c. 1995–2000)

Wage labor refers to the sale of labor under a formal or informal employment contract to an employer. These transactions usually occur in a labor market where wages are market determined. In Marxist economics, these owners of the means of production and suppliers of capital are generally called capitalists. The description of the role of the capitalist has shifted, first referring to a useless intermediary between producers, then to an employer of producers, and finally to the owners of the means of production. Labor includes all physical and mental human resources, including entrepreneurial capacity and management skills, which are required to produce products and services. Production is the act of making goods or services by applying labor power.

Criticism

Main article: Criticism of capitalism
The Industrial Workers of the World poster "Pyramid of Capitalist System" (1911)

Criticism of capitalism comes from various political and philosophical approaches, including anarchist, socialist, religious and nationalist viewpoints. Of those who oppose it or want to modify it, some believe that capitalism should be removed through revolution while others believe that it should be changed slowly through political reforms.

Prominent critiques of capitalism allege that it is inherently exploitative, alienating, unstable, unsustainable, and economically inefficient—and that it creates massive economic inequality, commodifies people, degrades the environment, is undemocratic, embeds uneven and underdevelopment between nation states, and leads to an erosion of human rights because of its incentivization of imperialist expansion and war.

Other critics argue that such inequities are not due to the ethic-neutral construct of the economic system commonly known as capitalism, but to the ethics of those who shape and execute the system. For example, some contend that Milton Friedman's (human) ethic of 'maximizing shareholder value' creates a harmful form of capitalism, while a Millard Fuller or John Bogle (human) ethic of 'enough' creates a sustainable form. Equitable ethics and unified ethical decision-making is theorized to create a less damaging form of capitalism.

Inheritance has been argued to not be a fundamental part of capitalism, instead part of nepotism.

See also

References

Notes
  1. Zimbalist, Andrew; Sherman, Howard J.; Brown, Stuart (October 1988). Comparing Economic Systems: A Political-Economic Approach. Harcourt College Publishing. pp. 6–7. ISBN 978-0-15-512403-5. Pure capitalism is defined as a system wherein all of the means of production (physical capital) are privately owned and run by the capitalist class for a profit, while most other people are workers who work for a salary or wage (and who do not own the capital or the product).
  2. Rosser, Mariana V.; Rosser, J Barkley (23 July 2003). Comparative Economics in a Transforming World Economy. MIT Press. p. 7. ISBN 978-0-262-18234-8. In capitalist economies, land and produced means of production (the capital stock) are owned by private individuals or groups of private individuals organized as firms.
  3. Jenks, Chris. Core Sociological Dichotomies. London; Thousand Oaks, CA; New Delhi: SAGE Publishing. p. 383. Capitalism, as a mode of production, is an economic system of manufacture and exchange which is geared toward the production and sale of commodities within a market for profit, where the manufacture of commodities consists of the use of the formally free labor of workers in exchange for a wage to create commodities in which the manufacturer extracts surplus value from the labor of the workers in terms of the difference between the wages paid to the worker and the value of the commodity produced by him/her to generate that profit.
  4. Gilpin, Robert (2018). The Challenge of Global Capitalism : The World Economy in the 21st Century. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-18647-4. OCLC 1076397003.
  5. Sternberg, Elaine (2015). "Defining Capitalism". Economic Affairs. 35 (3): 380–396. doi:10.1111/ecaf.12141. ISSN 0265-0665. S2CID 219373247.
  6. Heilbroner, Robert L. (2018). "Capitalism". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 1378–1389. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_154. ISBN 978-1-349-95189-5.
  7. Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (2015). Conceptualizing Capitalism: Institutions, Evolution, Future. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. ISBN 9780226168142.
  8. ^ Harris, Neal; Delanty, Gerard (2023). "What is capitalism? Toward a working definition". Social Science Information. 62 (3): 323–344. doi:10.1177/05390184231203878.
  9. Berend, Ivan T. (2015). "Capitalism". International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences (Second Edition): 94–98. doi:10.1016/B978-0-08-097086-8.62003-2. ISBN 978-0-08-097087-5.
  10. Antonio, Robert J.; Bonanno, Alessandro (2012). "Capitalism". The Wiley-Blackwell Encyclopedia of Globalization. doi:10.1002/9780470670590.wbeog060. ISBN 978-1-4051-8824-1.
  11. Beamish, Rob (2018). "Capitalism". Core Concepts in Sociology. pp. 17–22. doi:10.1002/9781394260331.ch6. ISBN 978-1-119-16861-4.
  12. Gregory, Paul; Stuart, Robert (2013). The Global Economy and its Economic Systems. South-Western College Publishing. p. 41. ISBN 978-1-285-05535-0. Capitalism is characterized by private ownership of the factors of production. Decision making is decentralized and rests with the owners of the factors of production. Their decision making is coordinated by the market, which provides the necessary information. Material incentives are used to motivate participants.
  13. Gregory, Paul; Stuart, Robert (2013). The Global Economy and its Economic Systems. South-Western College Publishing. p. 107. ISBN 978-1-285-05535-0. Real-world capitalist systems are mixed, some having higher shares of public ownership than others. The mix changes when privatization or nationalization occurs. Privatization is when property that had been state-owned is transferred to private owners. Nationalization occurs when privately owned property becomes publicly owned.
  14. ^ Macmillan Dictionary of Modern Economics (3rd ed.). 1986. p. 54.
  15. Bronk, Richard (Summer 2000). "Which model of capitalism?". OECD Observer. Vol. 1999, no. 221–222. OECD. pp. 12–15. Archived from the original on 6 April 2018. Retrieved 6 April 2018.
  16. Stilwell, Frank (2002). Political Economy: the Contest of Economic Ideas (1st ed.). Melbourne, Australia: Oxford University Press.
  17. ^ Hodrick, R.; Prescott, E. (1997). "Postwar US business cycles: An empirical investigation" (PDF). Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 29 (1): 1–16. doi:10.2307/2953682. JSTOR 2953682. S2CID 154995815.
  18. ^ Braudel, Fernand (1979). The Wheels of Commerce: Civilization and Capitalism 15th–18th Century. Harper and Row.
  19. ^ James Augustus Henry Murray. "Capital". A New English Dictionary on Historical Principles. Oxford English Press. Vol. 2. p. 93.
  20. E.g., "L'Angleterre a-t-elle l'heureux privilège de n'avoir ni Agioteurs, ni Banquiers, ni Faiseurs de services, ni Capitalistes ?" in (1788) De la foi publique envers les créanciers de l'état : lettres à M. Linguet sur le n° CXVI de ses annales p. 19 Archived 19 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine
  21. Arthur Young. Travels in France.
  22. Ricardo, David. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. 1821. John Murray Publisher, 3rd edition.
  23. Samuel Taylor Coleridge. Tabel The Complete Works of Samuel Taylor Coleridge Archived 23 February 2020 at the Wayback Machine. p. 267.
  24. Saunders, Peter (1995). Capitalism. University of Minnesota Press. p. 1.
  25. ^ MEW, 23, & Das Kapital. Kritik der politischen Oekonomie. Erster Band-Verlag von Otto Meissner (1867)
  26. The use of the word "capitalism" appears in Theories of Surplus Value, volume II. ToSV was edited by Kautsky.
  27. Hessen, Robert (2008) "Capitalism", in Henderson, David R. (ed.) The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics p. 57
  28. Harcourt, Bernard E. (2020) For Coöperation and the Abolition of Capital, Or, How to Get Beyond Our Extractive Punitive Society and Achieve a Just Society, Rochester, NY: Columbia Public Law Research Paper No. 14-672, p. 31
  29. James Augustus Henry Murray. "Capitalism" p. 94.
  30. Mandel, Ernst (2002). An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory. Resistance Books. p. 24. ISBN 978-1-876646-30-1. Archived from the original on 15 February 2017. Retrieved 29 January 2017.
  31. Werhane, P. H. (1994). "Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism". The Review of Metaphysics. 47 (3).
  32. ^ "Free enterprise". Roget's 21st Century Thesaurus (Third ed.). Philip Lief Group. 2008.
  33. ^ Capitalism. Encyclopædia Britannica. 10 November 2014. Archived from the original on 29 June 2011. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
  34. Barrons Dictionary of Finance and Investment Terms. 1995. p. 74.
  35. "Market economy". Merriam-Webster Unabridged Dictionary.
  36. Shutt, Harry (2010). Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for the Post-Capitalist Era. Zed Books. ISBN 978-1-84813-417-1.
  37. ^ Wolf, Harald (2004). "Capitalism". In Ritzer, George (ed.). Encyclopedia of Social Theory. Sage Publications. pp. 76–80. ISBN 978-1-4522-6546-9.
  38. Howard, M.C.; King, J.E. (January 2001). "'State Capitalism' in the Soviet Union". History of Economics Review. 34 (1): 110–126. doi:10.1080/10370196.2001.11733360. ISSN 1037-0196. S2CID 42809979.
  39. ^ Delacroix, Jacques (2007). "Capitalism". In Ritzer, George (ed.). Encyclopedia of Social Theory. Wiley. doi:10.1002/9781405165518.wbeosc004. ISBN 978-1-4051-2433-1.
  40. Acemoglu, Daron (2017). "Capitalism". In Frey, Bruno S.; Iselin, David (eds.). Economic Ideas You Should Forget. Springer. pp. 1–3. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-47458-8_1. ISBN 978-3-319-47457-1.
  41. Behringer, Wolfgang (2011). "Core and Periphery: The Holy Roman Empire as a Communication(s) Universe". The Holy Roman Empire, 1495–1806 (PDF). Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 347–358. ISBN 978-0-19-960297-1. Archived (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022. Retrieved 7 August 2022.
  42. "Cradle of capitalism". The Economist. 16 April 2009. Archived from the original on 18 January 2018. Retrieved 9 March 2015.
  43. Warburton, David (2003). Macroeconomics from the beginning: The General Theory, Ancient Markets, and the Rate of Interest. Paris: Recherches et Publications. p. 49.
  44. Koehler, Benedikt (2014). Early Islam and the Birth of Capitalism. Lexington Books. p. 2. In Baghdad, by the early tenth century a fully-fledged banking sector had come into being...
  45. Brenner, Robert (1 January 1982). "The Agrarian Roots of European Capitalism". Past & Present (97): 16–113. doi:10.1093/past/97.1.16. JSTOR 650630.
  46. "The Agrarian Origins of Capitalism". July 1998. Archived from the original on 11 December 2019. Retrieved 17 December 2012.
  47. An Introduction to Marxist Economic Theory. Resistance Books. 2002. ISBN 978-1-876646-30-1. Archived from the original on 11 December 2016. Retrieved 27 August 2016 – via Google Books.
  48. ^ Burnham, Peter (2003). Capitalism: The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics. Oxford University Press.
  49. ^ Scott, John (2005). Industrialism: A Dictionary of Sociology. Oxford University Press.
  50. Encyclopædia Britannica (2006)
  51. Polanyi, Karl (1944). The Great Transformation. Boston: Beacon Press. p. 87.
  52. Onnekink, David; Rommelse, Gijs (2011). Ideology and Foreign Policy in Early Modern Europe (1650–1750). Ashgate Publishing. p. 257. ISBN 978-1-4094-1914-3. Archived from the original on 19 March 2015. Retrieved 27 June 2015.
  53. Quoted in Clark, George (1961). The Seventeenth Century. New York: Oxford University Press. p. 24.
  54. Om Prakash, "Empire, Mughal", History of World Trade Since 1450, edited by John J. McCusker, vol. 1, Macmillan Reference USA, 2006, pp. 237–240, World History in Context. Retrieved 3 August 2017
  55. Ray, Indrajit (2011). Bengal Industries and the British Industrial Revolution (1757–1857). Routledge. pp. 57, 90, 174. ISBN 978-1-136-82552-1. Archived from the original on 29 May 2016. Retrieved 20 June 2019.
  56. ^ Banaji, Jairus (2007). "Islam, the Mediterranean and the rise of capitalism" (PDF). Journal Historical Materialism. 15: 47–74. doi:10.1163/156920607X171591. Archived from the original (PDF) on 29 March 2018. Retrieved 20 April 2018.
  57. Economic system:: Market systems. Encyclopædia Britannica. 2006. Archived from the original on 24 May 2009. Retrieved 4 January 2009.
  58. Watt steam engine image located in the lobby of the Superior Technical School of Industrial Engineers of the UPM (Madrid).
  59. Hume, David (1752). Political Discourses. Edinburgh: A. Kincaid & A. Donaldson.
  60. Burnham, Peter (1996). "Capitalism". In McLean, Iain; McMillan, Alistair (eds.). The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics. Oxford Quick Reference (3 ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press (published 2009). ISBN 978-0-19-101827-5. Archived from the original on 27 July 2020. Retrieved 14 September 2019. Industrial capitalism, which Marx dates from the last third of the eighteenth century, finally establishes the domination of the capitalist mode of production.
  61. "Laissez-faire". Archived from the original on 2 December 2008.
  62. Burnham, Peter (1996). "Capitalism". In McLean, Iain; McMillan, Alistair (eds.). The Concise Oxford Dictionary of Politics. Oxford Quick Reference (3 ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press (published 2009). ISBN 978-0-19-101827-5. Archived from the original on 27 July 2020. Retrieved 14 September 2019. For most analysts, mid- to late-nineteenth century Britain is seen as the apotheosis of the laissez-faire phase of capitalism. This phase took off in Britain in the 1840s with the repeal of the Corn Laws, and the Navigation Acts, and the passing of the Banking Act.
  63. ^ James, Paul; Gills, Barry (2007). Globalization and Economy, Vol. 1: Global Markets and Capitalism. London: SAGE Publications. p. xxxiii.
  64. "Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies" (PDF). Impact of Global Capitalism on the Environment of Developing Economies: The Case of Nigeria: 84. Archived (PDF) from the original on 20 March 2020. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
  65. James, Fulcher (2004). Capitalism, A Very Short Introduction. Oxford University Press. p. 99. ISBN 978-0-19-280218-7. In one respect there can, however, be little doubt that capitalism has gone global and that is in the elimination of alternative systems
  66. Thomas, Martin; Thompson, Andrew (1 January 2014). "Empire and Globalisation: from 'High Imperialism' to Decolonisation". The International History Review. 36 (1): 142–170. doi:10.1080/07075332.2013.828643. ISSN 0707-5332. S2CID 153987517.
  67. "Globalization and Empire" (PDF). Globalization and Empire. Archived (PDF) from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
  68. "Europe and the causes of globalization" (PDF). Europe and the Causes of Globalization, 1790 to 2000. Archived (PDF) from the original on 7 December 2017. Retrieved 31 July 2020.
  69. "Commanding Heights: Episode One: The Battle of Ideas". PBS. 24 October 1929. Archived from the original on 30 March 2010. Retrieved 31 July 2010.
  70. Eichengreen, Barry (6 August 2019). Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (3rd ed.). Princeton University Press. doi:10.2307/j.ctvd58rxg. ISBN 978-0-691-19458-5. LCCN 2019018286. S2CID 240840930.
  71. Eichengreen, Barry; Esteves, Rui Pedro (2021). "International Finance". In Fukao, Kyoji; Broadberry, Stephen (eds.). The Cambridge Economic History of the Modern World. Vol. 2: 1870 to the Present. Cambridge University Press. pp. 501–525. ISBN 978-1-107-15948-8.
  72. Bordo, Michael D.; Eichengreen, Barry; Irwin, Douglas A. (June 1999). "Is Globalization Today Really Different than Globalization a Hundred Years Ago?". NBER. doi:10.3386/w7195.
  73. Andrews, Thomas G. (2008). Killing for Coal: America's Deadliest Labor War. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. p. 64. ISBN 978-0-674-03101-2.
  74. Crosland, Anthony (1956). The Future of Socialism. United Kingdom: Jonathan Cape.
  75. Galbraith, John Kenneth (1958). The Affluent Society. United States: Houghton Mifflin.
  76. Shiller, Robert (2012). Finance and The Good Society. United States: Princeton University Press.
  77. Barnes, Trevor J. (2004). Reading economic geography. Blackwell Publishing. p. 127. ISBN 978-0-631-23554-5.
  78. Fulcher, James (2004). Capitalism (1st ed.). New York: Oxford University Press.
  79. Gerstle, Gary (2022). The Rise and Fall of the Neoliberal Order: America and the World in the Free Market Era. Oxford University Press. pp. 10–12. ISBN 978-0-19-751964-6.
  80. Bartel, Fritz (2022). The Triumph of Broken Promises: The End of the Cold War and the Rise of Neoliberalism. Harvard University Press. pp. 5–6, 19. ISBN 978-0-674-97678-8.
  81. Rodrik, Dani (2009), Hemerijck, Anton; Knapen, Ben; van Doorne, Ellen (eds.), "Capitalism 3.0", Aftershocks, Amsterdam University Press, pp. 185–193, ISBN 978-90-8964-192-2, JSTOR j.ctt46mtqx.23, retrieved 14 January 2021
  82. Milner, Helen V (2021). "Is Global Capitalism Compatible with Democracy? Inequality, Insecurity, and Interdependence". International Studies Quarterly. 65 (4): 1097–1110. doi:10.1093/isq/sqab056.
  83. Epstein, Gady. "The Winners And Losers in Chinese Capitalism". Forbes. Archived from the original on 5 November 2015. Retrieved 28 October 2015.
  84. "The rise of state capitalism". The Economist. ISSN 0013-0613. Archived from the original on 15 June 2020. Retrieved 24 October 2015.
  85. Mesquita, Bruce Bueno de (September 2005). "Development and Democracy". Foreign Affairs. Archived from the original on 20 February 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
  86. Siegle, Joseph; Weinstein, Michael; Halperin, Morton (1 September 2004). "Why Democracies Excel" (PDF). Foreign Affairs. 83 (5): 57. doi:10.2307/20034067. JSTOR 20034067. Archived (PDF) from the original on 12 April 2019. Retrieved 26 August 2018.
  87. Iversen, Torben; Soskice, David (2019). Democracy and Prosperity: Reinventing Capitalism through a Turbulent Century. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-18273-5. JSTOR j.ctv4g1r3n.
  88. ^ Dahl, Robert A. (2020). On Democracy. Yale University Press. ISBN 978-0-300-25799-1.
  89. Pryor, Frederic L. (2010). "Capitalism and freedom?". Economic Systems. 34 (1): 91–104. doi:10.1016/j.ecosys.2009.09.003.
  90. Hayek, Friedrich (1944). "The Road to Serfdom". Nature. 154 (3911). University of Chicago Press: 473–474. Bibcode:1944Natur.154..473C. doi:10.1038/154473a0. ISBN 978-0-226-32061-8. S2CID 4071358.
  91. Bellamy, Richard (2003). The Cambridge History of Twentieth-Century Political Thought. Cambridge University Press. p. 60. ISBN 978-0-521-56354-3.
  92. Karatnycky, Adrian (2001). Freedom in the World: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties. Transaction Publishers. p. 11. ISBN 978-0-7658-0101-2.
  93. Piketty, Thomas (2014). Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Belknap Press. p. 571. ISBN 978-0-674-43000-6.
  94. "Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015". Transparency International Corruption Measure 2015 – By Country / Territory. Transparency International. Archived from the original on 31 March 2016. Retrieved 20 September 2016.
  95. Klein, Naomi (2008). The Shock Doctrine: The Rise of Disaster Capitalism. Picador. ISBN 0-312-42799-9 p. 105 Archived 19 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine.
  96. Farid, Hilmar (2005). "Indonesia's original sin: mass killings and capitalist expansion, 1965–66". Inter-Asia Cultural Studies. 6 (1): 3–16. doi:10.1080/1462394042000326879. S2CID 145130614.
  97. Robinson, Geoffrey B. (2018). The Killing Season: A History of the Indonesian Massacres, 1965–66. Princeton University Press. p. 177. ISBN 978-1-4008-8886-3. Archived from the original on 19 April 2019. Retrieved 1 August 2018.
  98. ""capitalism, n.2". OED Online". Archived from the original on 23 September 2020. Retrieved 19 January 2013.
  99. ^ Williams, Raymond (1983). "Capitalism". Keywords: A vocabulary of culture and society, revised edition. Oxford University Press. p. 51. ISBN 978-0-19-520469-8.
  100. "Althusser and the Renewal of Marxist Social Theory". Archived from the original on 2 April 2015. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
  101. ^ Marx, Karl. "Thirty Two". Economic Manuscripts: Capital Vol. I. Archived from the original on 21 February 2015. Retrieved 24 March 2015 – via Marxists Internet Archive.
  102. ^ "The contradictions of capitalism – Democratic Socialist Perspective". dsp.org.au. Archived from the original on 6 April 2015.
  103. Goldberg, Victor P. (21 November 2012). "Contracts". The Oxford Handbook of Capitalism. Oxford University Press. pp. 250–274. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195391176.013.0010. ISBN 978-0-19-539117-6.
  104. ^ Steinfeld 2009, p. 3: "All labor contracts were/are designed legally to bind a worker in one way or another to fulfill the labor obligations the worker has undertaken. That is one of the principal purposes of labor contracts."
  105. James Fulcher, Capitalism A Very Short Introduction, "the investment of money in order to make a profit, the essential feature of capitalism", p. 14, Oxford, 2004, ISBN 978-0-19-280218-7.
  106. Reisman, George (1998). Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life. Jameson Books. ISBN 0-915463-73-3.
  107. Hunt, E.K.; Lautzenheiser, Mark (2014). History of Economic Thought: A Critical Perspective. PHI Learning. ISBN 978-0-7656-2599-1.
  108. Reisman, George (1998). Capitalism: A complete understanding of the nature and value of human economic life. Jameson Books. ISBN 978-0-915463-73-2.
  109. ^ Wright, Edmund, ed. (2006). The Desk Encyclopedia of World History. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 111–112. ISBN 978-0-7394-7809-7.
  110. James Fulcher, Capitalism A Very Short Introduction, "...in the wake of the 1970 crisis, the neoliberal model of capitalism became intellectually and ideologically dominant", p. 58, Oxford, 2004, ISBN 978-0-19-280218-7.
  111. "Monopoly". Investopedia. 24 November 2003. Archived from the original on 22 February 2017. Retrieved 2 March 2017.
  112. Deakin & Wilkinson 2005
  113. Editorial Board (2013). "W". Concise Dictionary of Economics. V&S Publishers. p. 278. ISBN 978-93-5057-032-6.
  114. Compare: Duska, Ronald F. (1997). "The Why's of Business Revisited". Contemporary Reflections on Business Ethics. Issues in Business Ethics. Vol. 23. Dordrecht: Springer Science & Business Media (published 2007). p. 41. ISBN 978-1-4020-4984-2. Retrieved 8 July 2019. In microeconomics courses, profit maximization is frequently given as the goal of the firm. ... In microeconomics, profit maximization functions largely as a theoretical goal, with economists using it to prove how firms behave rationally to increase profit. Unfortunately, it ignores many real-world complexities.
  115. Hazlitt, Henry. "The Function of Profits". Economics in One Lesson. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. Web. 22 April 2013.
  116. "What is capitalism" Australian Socialist https://search.informit.org/doi/10.3316/informit.818838886883514
  117. Hernando de Soto. "The mystery of capital". Archived from the original on 8 February 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
  118. Karl Marx. "Capital, v. 1. Part VIII: primitive accumulation". Archived from the original on 3 March 2008. Retrieved 26 February 2008.
  119. N.F.R. Crafts (April 1978). "Enclosure and labor supply revisited". Explorations in Economic History. 15 (2): 172–183. doi:10.1016/0014-4983(78)90019-0.
  120. "Definition of COMPETITION". Archived from the original on 4 July 2008. Retrieved 24 March 2015.
  121. Stigler, George J. (2008). "competition". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.). Archived from the original on 15 February 2015.
  122. Blaug, Mark (2008). "Invisible hand". The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 4 (2nd ed.). p. 565. Archived from the original on 5 June 2013.
  123. ^ Heyne, Paul; Boettke, Peter J.; Prychitko, David L. (2014). The Economic Way of Thinking (13th ed.). Pearson. pp. 102–106. ISBN 978-0-13-299129-2.
  124. ^ Warsh, David (2007). Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations. W.W. Norton. p. 42.
  125. Lippit, Victor (2005). Capitalism. ProQuest: Taylor & Francis. p. 2.
  126. Joff, Michael (2011). "The root cause of economic growth under capitalism". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 35 (5): 873–896. doi:10.1093/cje/beq054. The tendency for capitalist economies to grow is one of their most characteristic properties.
  127. Baumol, William J. (2004). The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691116303.
  128. Encyclopedia of Marxism at marxism.org. "Capitalism". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 7 May 2019. Retrieved 8 July 2011.
  129. "Capitalism". Investopedia. Retrieved 14 February 2022.
  130. "Capitalism." World Book Encyclopedia. 1988. p. 194.
  131. Besanko, David; Braeutigam, Ronald (2010). Microeconomics (4th ed.). Wiley.
  132. "Supply". Boundless Economics. 13 June 2017. Retrieved 27 October 2021.
  133. Unlike most graphs, supply & demand curves are plotted with the independent variable (price) on the vertical axis and the dependent variable (quantity supplied or demanded) on the horizontal axis.
  134. "Marginal Utility and Demand". Archived from the original on 6 November 2006. Retrieved 9 February 2007.
  135. Varian, Hal R. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 978-0-393-95735-8.
  136. Jain, T.R. (2006). Microeconomics and Basic Mathematics. New Delhi: VK Publications. p. 28. ISBN 978-81-87140-89-4.
  137. Hosseini, Hamid S. (2003). "Contributions of Medieval Muslim Scholars to the History of Economics and their Impact: A Refutation of the Schumpeterian Great Gap". In Biddle, Jeff E.; Davis, Jon B.; Samuels, Warren J. (eds.). A Companion to the History of Economic Thought. Malden, Massachusetts: Blackwell. pp. 28–45 . doi:10.1002/9780470999059.ch3. ISBN 978-0-631-22573-7. (citing Hamid S. Hosseini, 1995. "Understanding the Market Mechanism Before Adam Smith: Economic Thought in Medieval Islam," History of Political Economy, Vol. 27, No. 3, 539–561).
  138. John Locke (1691) Some Considerations on the consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money Archived 24 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine
  139. ^ Thomas M. Humphrey, 1992. "Marshallian Cross Diagrams and Their Uses before Alfred Marshall", Economic Review, Mar/Apr, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, pp. 3–23 Archived 19 October 2012 at the Wayback Machine.
  140. A.D. Brownlie and M.F. Lloyd Prichard, 1963. "Professor Fleeming Jenkin, 1833–1885 Pioneer in Engineering and Political Economy", Oxford Economic Papers, 15(3), p. 211.
  141. Fleeming Jenkin, 1870. "The Graphical Representation of the Laws of Supply and Demand, and their Application to Labour", in Alexander Grant, ed., Recess Studies, Edinburgh. Ch. VI, pp. 151–185. Edinburgh. Scroll to chapter link Archived 16 July 2020 at the Wayback Machine.
  142. Hall, Peter A.; Soskice, David (20 September 2001). Varieties Of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford University Press, U.S.A. ISBN 0-19-924775-7.
  143. Lears, T.J. Jackson (1985) "The Concept of Cultural Hegemony"
  144. Holub, Renate (2005) Antonio Gramsci: Beyond Marxism and Postmodernism
  145. Boggs, Carl (2012) Ecology and Revolution: Global Crisis and the Political Challenge
  146. Habermas, 1988: 37, 75.
  147. Barnett, H C (January 1981). "Crime and Delinquency". Office of Justice Programs.
  148. Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism ibid. Finance Capital and the Finance Oligarchy Archived 2 April 2015 at the Wayback Machine
  149. Foster, John Bellamy; McChesney, Robert W. (1 October 2009). "Monopoly-Finance Capital and the Paradox of Accumulation". Monthly Review. Archived from the original on 28 August 2016. Retrieved 27 August 2016.
  150. Frederic Jameson, 'Culture and Finance Capital', in The Jameson Reader (2005) p. 257
  151. Quoted in E.H. Carr, The Bolshevik Revolution 2 (1971) p. 137
  152. Quoted in F.A Voight, Unto Caesar (1938) p. 22
  153. C. J.Calhoun/G. Derluguian, Business as Usual (2011) p. 57
  154. Jameson, pp. 259–260
  155. Jahan, Sarwat; Saber Mahmud, Ahmed. "What Is Capitalism?". International Monetary Fund.
  156. "Laissez-faire". Encyclopædia Britannica.
  157. "Anarcho-capitalism". Encyclopædia Britannica.
  158. Perumal J., Prashanth (13 December 2023). "Understanding the debates around anarcho-capitalism". The Hindu. Archived from the original on 13 December 2023.
  159. Braudel, F.; Ranum, P.M.; Ranum, P.P. (1977). Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism. Johns Hopkins symposia in comparative history. Johns Hopkins University Press. pp. 47–63. ISBN 978-0-8018-1901-8. Retrieved 6 April 2022.
  160. "Mercantilism". Encyclopædia Britannica.
  161. Müller-Armack, Alfred (28 July 2006). "The Social Market Economy as an Economic and Social order". Taylor & Francis.
  162. "Rhenish Capitalism". Oxford University Press.
  163. Musacchio, Aldo. "Economist Debates: State capitalism: Statements". The Economist. Archived from the original on 16 July 2012. Retrieved 20 June 2012.
  164. State capitalism Archived 3 July 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Merriam-Webster. Retrieved 7 July 2015.
  165. Engels, Frederick. "Socialism: Utopian and Scientific (Chpt. 3)". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 9 May 2020. Retrieved 8 January 2014.
  166. V.I. Lenin. The Tax in Kind Archived 7 September 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Lenin's Collected Works, 1st English ed., Progress Publishers, Moscow, 1965, vol. 32, pp. 329–365.
  167. V.I. Lenin. To the Russian Colony in North America Archived 18 June 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Lenin Collected Works, Progress Publishers, 1971, Moscow, vol. 42, pp. 425c–427a.
  168. "State capitalism" in the Soviet Union Archived 28 July 2019 at the Wayback Machine, M.C. Howard and J.E. King
  169. Noam Chomsky (1986). The Soviet Union Versus Socialism Archived 24 September 2015 at the Wayback Machine. Our Generation. Retrieved 9 July 2015.
  170. Richard D. Wolff (27 June 2015). Socialism Means Abolishing the Distinction Between Bosses and Employees Archived 11 March 2018 at the Wayback Machine. Truthout. Retrieved 9 July 2015.
  171. Dunayevskaya, Raya (1941). "The Union of Soviet Socialist Republics is a Capitalist Society". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 7 December 2019.
  172. James, C.L.R.; Dunayevskaya, Raya; Boggs, Grace Lee (1950). "State Capitalism and World Revolution" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 19 June 2020.
  173. Von Mises, Ludwig (1979). Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. Indianapolis: LibertyClassics. ISBN 978-0-913966-63-1. Retrieved 31 May 2007. The socialist movement takes great pains to circulate frequently new labels for its ideally constructed state. Each worn-out label is replaced by another which raises hopes of an ultimate solution of the insoluble basic problem of Socialism—until it becomes obvious that nothing has been changed but the name. The most recent slogan is 'State Capitalism.' It is not commonly realized that this covers nothing more than what used to be called Planned Economy and State Socialism, and that State Capitalism, Planned Economy, and State Socialism diverge only in non-essentials from the "classic" ideal of egalitarian Socialism.
  174. Esping-Andersen, Gøsta (1990). The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton University Press. ISBN 9780691028576.
  175. Piketty, Thomas (2013). "Repenser l'impôt progressif sur le revenu" [To rethink income tax progressivity]. Le capital au XXIe siècle (in French). Éditions du Seuil. pp. 799, 800. ISBN 978-2-02-108228-9. Si cette régressivité fiscale au sommet de la hiérarchie sociale devait se confirmer et s'amplifier à l'avenir, il est bien évident qu'une telle sécession fiscale des plus riches est potentiellement extrêmement dommageable pour le consentement fiscal dans son ensemble s'en trouve amoindri . Il est vital pour l'État social moderne que le système fiscal qui le sous-tend conserve un minimum de progressivité. [If tax regressivity on top of the social hierarchy may settle in and escalate in the future, it is obvious that such a tax secession between the richest and the other classes will be highly harmful towards the agreement over the taxation system which will weaken. It is essential for the modern social system that the taxation system preserve a sort of tax progressivity.]
  176. Balch, Oliver (24 November 2019). "Green capitalism sometimes also referring to sustainable businesses". The Guardian.
  177. "Definition of Eco-Capitalism". collinsdictionary.com. Retrieved 27 November 2015.
  178. "The rise of green capitalism". roadtoparis.info. Retrieved 27 November 2015.
  179. Mitra, Basavadatta; Gadhok, Saagar; Salhotra, Shivam; Agarwal, Sakshi (2011). "The convergence of sustainable capitalism". 2011 IEEE International Professional Communication Conference. pp. 1–7. doi:10.1109/IPCC.2011.6087226. ISBN 978-1-61284-779-5. S2CID 31292223.
  180. Schweickart, David (1 January 2009). "Is Sustainable Capitalism an Oxymoron?". Perspectives on Global Development and Technology. 8 (2–3): 559–580. doi:10.1163/156914909X424033.
  181. E., Harrison, Neil (1 January 2013). Sustainable Capitalism and the Pursuit of Well-Being. Routledge. ISBN 978-1-306-21804-7. OCLC 866837827.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  182. ^ Gore, Al; Blood, David. "A Manifesto for Sustainable Capitalism" (PDF). Generation Foundation. Archived from the original (PDF) on 24 January 2014. Retrieved 24 October 2022.
  183. "Sustainable Capitalism" (PDF). Archived (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022. Retrieved 18 February 2017.
  184. "Economics A–Z: Capital". The Economist. Archived from the original on 7 August 2017. Retrieved 25 March 2015.
  185. "Encyclopedia of Marxism – Glossary of terms: Capital". Marxists Internet Archive. Archived from the original on 18 June 2015. Retrieved 25 March 2015.
  186. Deakin & Wilkinson 2005.
    Marx 1990, p. 1005, defines wage labour succinctly as "the labour of the worker who sells his own labour-power."
  187. Ragan, Christopher T.S.; Lipsey, Richard G. Microeconomics. 12th Canadian ed. Toronto, Pearson Education, 2008. ISBN 978-0-321-31491-8
  188. Robbins, Richard H. Global problems and the culture of capitalism. Boston: Allyn & Bacon, 2007. ISBN 978-0-205-52487-7
  189. Tormey, Simon (2004). Anticapitalism. One World Publications. p. 10. ISBN 978-1-78074-250-2.
  190. "16.1C: The Marxist Critique of Capitalism". Book: Sociology (Boundless). LibreTexts. 16 December 2020. Retrieved 21 October 2021. Revolutionary socialists believe that capitalism can only be overcome through revolution. Social democrats believe that structural change can come slowly through political reforms to capitalism.
  191. Pons, Silvio; Smith, Stephen A., eds. (21 September 2017). The Cambridge History of Communism. Cambridge University Press. pp. 49–73. doi:10.1017/9781316137024. ISBN 978-1-316-13702-4.
  192. Engels, Frederick. "Competition – The Condition of the Working Class in England". Retrieved 10 March 2008.
  193. "Exploitation". Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. 20 December 2001. Archived from the original on 27 November 2020. Retrieved 26 December 2020.
  194. Mattei, Clara E. (2022). The Capital Order: How Economists Invented Austerity and Paved the Way to Fascism. University of Chicago Press. pp. 17–18. ISBN 978-0-226-81839-9.
  195. "Alienation." Pp. 10. in A Dictionary of Philosophy (rev. 2nd ed.). 1984.
  196. Engels, Frederick. "On the Question of Free Trade". Retrieved 11 March 2008.
  197. Easterling, Earl. "Marx's Theory of Economic Crisis". International Socialist Review. Archived from the original on 27 February 2021. Retrieved 13 March 2008.
  198. ^ Dawson, Ashley (2016). Extinction: A Radical History. OR Books. p. 41. ISBN 978-1-944869-01-4. Archived from the original on 17 September 2016. Retrieved 20 August 2016.
  199. Nelson, Anitra (31 January 2024). "Degrowth as a Concept and Practice : Introduction". The Commons Social Change Library. Retrieved 24 February 2024.
  200. Fletcher, Charles; Ripple, William J.; Newsome, Thomas; Barnard, Phoebe; Beamer, Kamanamaikalani; Behl, Aishwarya; Bowen, Jay; Cooney, Michael; Crist, Eileen; Field, Christopher; Hiser, Krista; Karl, David M.; King, David A.; Mann, Michael E.; McGregor, Davianna P.; Mora, Camilo; Oreskes, Naomi; Wilson, Michael (4 April 2024). "Earth at risk: An urgent call to end the age of destruction and forge a just and sustainable future". PNAS Nexus. 3 (4): pgae106. doi:10.1093/pnasnexus/pgae106. PMC 10986754. PMID 38566756. Retrieved 4 April 2024.
  201. Shutt, Harry (March 2010). Beyond the Profits System: Possibilities for a post-capitalist era. Zed Books. ISBN 978-1-84813-417-1.
  202. Rogers, Heather. "The Conquest of Garbage". isreview.org. International Socialist Review (1997). Archived from the original on 10 May 2021. Retrieved 13 March 2008.
  203. Rea, K.J. "Monopoly, Imperfect Competition, and Oligopoly". Archived from the original on 12 June 2010. Retrieved 11 March 2008.
  204. King, Matthew Wilburn (25 May 2021). "Why the next stage of capitalism is coming". BBC Future. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
  205. Ghodsee, Kristen; Orenstein, Mitchell A. (2021). Taking Stock of Shock: Social Consequences of the 1989 Revolutions. Oxford University Press. p. 192. doi:10.1093/oso/9780197549230.001.0001. ISBN 978-0-19-754924-7. Without an accompanying welfare state in which social programs funded by a progressive income tax redistribute from the rich to the poor, capitalism can be a deeply unfair system where a small, well-connected elite captures a majority of the wealth and power, and not necessarily through meritocratic processes.
  206. Colin Leys (2 April 2021). "Commodification: the essence of our time". openDemocracy. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
  207. Daniel Margrain (25 August 2019). "The Commodification of Everything". Renegade Inc. Archived from the original on 21 October 2021. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
  208. Hickel, Jason (2021). Less is More: How Degrowth Will Save the World. Windmill Books. pp. 39–40. ISBN 978-1-78609-121-5. It was only with the rise of capitalism over the past few hundred years, and the breathtaking acceleration of industrialization from the 1950s, that on a planetary scale things began to tip out of balance.
  209. Merkel, Wolfgang (26 July 2014). "Is capitalism compatible with democracy?". Zeitschrift für Vergleichende Politikwissenschaft. 8 (2). Springer Science and Business Media LLC: 109–128. doi:10.1007/s12286-014-0199-4. hdl:10419/270951. ISSN 1865-2646. S2CID 150776013.
  210. Reich, Robert B. (12 October 2009). "How Capitalism Is Killing Democracy". Foreign Policy. Retrieved 21 October 2021.
  211. Slobodian, Quinn (2023). Crack-Up Capitalism: Market Radicals and the Dream of a World Without Democracy. Metropolitan Books. p. 10. ISBN 978-1-250-75389-2.
  212. Patnaik, Utsa (1982). "'Neo-Marxian' Theories of Capitalism and Underdevelopment: Towards a Critique". Social Scientist. 10 (11): 3–32. doi:10.2307/3516858. ISSN 0970-0293. JSTOR 3516858.
  213. Warke, Thomas W. (1973). "The Marxian Theory of Underdevelopment: A Review Article". The Journal of Developing Areas. 7 (4): 699–710. ISSN 0022-037X.
  214. Martins, Carlos Eduardo (January 2022). "The Longue Durée of the Marxist Theory of Dependency and the Twenty-First Century". Latin American Perspectives. 49 (1): 18–35. doi:10.1177/0094582X211052029. ISSN 0094-582X.
  215. Peck, Jamie; Varadarajan, Latha (6 March 2017). "Uneven Regional Development". International Encyclopedia of Geography: People, the Earth, Environment and Technology. John Wiley & Sons, Ltd: 1–13. doi:10.1002/9781118786352.wbieg0721. ISBN 9780470659632.
  216. Abeles, Marc (2006). "Globalization, Power, and Survival: an Anthropological Perspective" (PDF). Anthropological Quarterly. 79 (3): 484–486. doi:10.1353/anq.2006.0030. S2CID 144220354. Archived (PDF) from the original on 9 October 2022.
  217. Farid, Hilmar (2005). "Indonesia's original sin: mass killings and capitalist expansion, 1965–66". Inter-Asia Cultural Studies. 6 (1): 3–16. doi:10.1080/1462394042000326879. S2CID 145130614.
  218. Blakeley, Ruth (2009). State Terrorism and Neoliberalism: The North in the South. Routledge. pp. 4, 20–23, 88. ISBN 978-0-415-68617-4.
  219. Lenin's Selected Works, Progress Publishers, 1963, Moscow, Volume 1, pp. 667–766
  220. Stout, Lynn (2012). The Shareholder Value Myth. San Francisco, CA: Berrett-Koehler Publishers, Inc. pp. 15–23. ISBN 978-1-60509-813-5.
  221. Gelles, David (2022). The Man Who Broke Capitalism. New York: Simon & Schuster. pp. 1–13. ISBN 978-1-9821-7644-0.
  222. Fuller, Millard (1994). The Theology of the Hammer. Macon, GA: Smyth & Helwys Publishing. pp. 31–39. ISBN 1-880837-92-7.
  223. Bogle, John (2009). Enough. Hoboken, New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons. pp. 229–248. ISBN 978-0-470-52423-7.
  224. Knowlton & Hedges (2021). Better Capitalism. Eugene, OR: Wipf & Stock Publishers. pp. 34–37, 235–242. ISBN 978-1-7252-8093-9.
  225. Haslett, D. W. (1986). "Is Inheritance Justified?". Philosophy & Public Affairs. 15 (2). Wiley: 122–155. ISSN 0048-3915. JSTOR 2265382. Retrieved 17 August 2024.
  226. Pérez-González, Francisco (1 November 2006). "Inherited Control and Firm Performance". American Economic Review. 96 (5): 1559–1588. doi:10.1257/aer.96.5.1559. ISSN 0002-8282.
Bibliography

Further reading

External links

Library resources about
Capitalism
Capitalism
Aspects and perspectives
General
Ideology
  • Anglo-Saxon
  • Authoritarian
  • Conservative
  • Corporate
  • Democratic
  • Dirigist
  • Free-market
  • Humanistic
  • Laissez-faire
  • Liberal
  • Libertarian
  • Market
  • Mercantilist
  • Mixed
  • Monopoly
  • National
  • Neo
  • Neoliberal
  • Nordic
  • Private
  • Raw
  • Regulated market
  • Regulatory
  • Rhine
  • Social
  • State
  • State-sponsored
  • Welfare
  • Cultural aspects
  • Advertising
  • American Dream
  • Black Friday
  • Consumerism
  • Decentralization
  • Economic freedom
  • Economic mobility
  • Individualism
  • Liberalism
  • Liberty
  • Mainstream
  • Philanthropy
  • Private foundation
  • Private property
  • Rule of law
  • Social alienation
  • Spontaneous order
  • Social aspects
  • Corporatism
  • Economic inequality
  • Employment
  • Freedom of association
  • Labour market flexibility
  • Labour supply
  • Productivity
  • Prosperity
  • Syndicate
  • Social venture capital
  • Unemployment
  • Criticism
  • Anti-capitalism
  • Capitalist propaganda
  • Critique of political economy
  • Critique of work
  • Market fundamentalism
  • Marxism
  • Wage slavery
  • Antithesis
  • Anarchism
  • Anarcho-communism
  • Anarcho-primitivism
  • Anarcho-syndicalism
  • Collectivist anarchism
  • Communalism
  • Communism
  • Economic democracy
  • Eco-socialism
  • Free-market socialism
  • Green anarchism
  • Individualist anarchism
  • Libertarian socialism
  • Market anarchism
  • Market socialism
  • Mutualism
  • Post-capitalism
  • Post-scarcity economy
  • Sharing economy
  • Social anarchism
  • Socialism
  • Syndicalism
  • Links to related articles
    Political ideologies
    See also
    Political philosophy
    Terms
    Government
    Ideologies
    Concepts
    Philosophers
    Antiquity
    Middle Ages
    Early modern
    period
    18th and 19th
    centuries
    20th and 21st
    centuries
    Works
    Related
    Marxist phraseology and terminology
    Philosophy and politics
    (Marxist)
    Sociology and economics
    (Marxian)
    Marxist–Leninist
    Trotskyist
    Maoist
    Other
    Western world and culture
    Foundations
    History
    Culture
    Philosophy
    Religion
    Law
    Contemporary
    integration
    Portals: Categories: