Misplaced Pages

Seats-to-votes ratio

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Measure of equal representation

The seats-to-votes ratio, also known as the advantage ratio, is a measure of equal representation of voters. The equation for seats-to-votes ratio for a political party i is:

a i = s i / v i {\displaystyle \mathrm {a_{i}} =s_{i}/v_{i}} ,

where v i {\displaystyle \mathrm {v_{i}} } is fraction of votes cast for that party and s i {\displaystyle s_{i}} is fraction of seats won by that party.

In the case both seats and votes are represented as fractions or percentages, then every voter has equal representation if the seats-to-votes ratio is 1. The principle of equal representation is expressed in slogan one man, one vote and relates to proportional representation. The seats-to-votes ratio is used as the basis for the Gallagher index method of analyzing proportionality or disproportionality.

Related is the votes-per-seat-won, which is inverse to the seats-to-votes ratio.

Also related are the principles of one man one vote and representation by population.

Relation to disproportionality indices

The Sainte-Laguë Index is a disproportionality index derived by applying the Pearson's chi-squared test to the seats-to-votes ratio, the Gallagher index has a similar formula.

Seats-to-votes ratio for seat allocation to parties

Different apportionment methods such as Sainte-Laguë method and D'Hondt method differ in the seats-to-votes ratio for individual parties.

Seats-to-votes ratio for Sainte-Laguë method

Main article: Sainte-Laguë method § Proportionality under Sainte-Laguë method

The Sainte-Laguë method optimizes the seats-to-votes ratio among all parties i {\displaystyle i} with the least squares approach.

Disproportionality, the difference of the parties' seats-to-votes ratio and the ideal seats-to-votes ratio for each party, is squared, weighted according to the vote share of each party and summed up:

e r r o r = i v i ( s i v i 1 ) 2 {\displaystyle error=\sum _{i}{v_{i}*\left({\frac {s_{i}}{v_{i}}}-1\right)^{2}}}

It was shown that this error is minimized by the Sainte-Laguë method.

Seats-to-votes ratio for D'Hondt method

Main article: D'Hondt method § Approximate proportionality under D'Hondt

The D'Hondt method approximates proportionality by minimizing the largest seats-to-votes ratio among all parties. The largest seats-to-votes ratio, which measures how over-represented the most over-represented party among all parties is:

δ = max i a i , {\displaystyle \delta =\max _{i}a_{i},}

The D'Hondt method minimizes the largest seats-to-votes ratio by assigning the seats,

δ = min s S max i a i , {\displaystyle \delta ^{*}=\min _{\mathbf {s} \in {\mathcal {S}}}\max _{i}a_{i},}

where s {\displaystyle \mathbf {s} } is a seat allocation from the set of all allowed seat allocations S {\displaystyle {\mathcal {S}}} .

Notes

  1. Niemi, Richard G. "Relationship between Votes and Seats: The Ultimate Question in Political Gerrymandering." UCLA L. Rev. 33 (1985): 185.
  2. ^ Sainte-Laguë, André. "La représentation proportionnelle et la méthode des moindres carrés." Annales scientifiques de l'école Normale Supérieure. Vol. 27. 1910.
  3. General Election 2019: Turning votes into seats, Published Friday, 10 January, 2020, Roderick McInnes, UK Parliament, House of Commons Library
  4. Goldenberg, Josh; Fisher, Stephen D. (2019). "The Sainte-Laguë index of disproportionality and Dalton's principle of transfers". Party Politics. 25 (2): 203–207. doi:10.1177/1354068817703020.
  5. Juraj Medzihorsky (2019). "Rethinking the D'Hondt method". Political Research Exchange. 1 (1): 1625712. doi:10.1080/2474736X.2019.1625712.
Electoral systems
Part of the politics and Economics series
Single-winner
Proportional
Systems
Allocation
Quotas
Mixed
Semi-proportional
Criteria
Other
Comparison
PortalProject
Categories: